Mexico and the World
Vol. 4, No 1 (Winter 1999)
http://www.profmex.org/mexicoandtheworld/volume4/1winter99/regional_change.html
RECENT REGIONAL CHANGE AND PRODUCTIVITY IN MEXICO
Adrián de León Arias
Universidad de Guadalajara
ABSTRACT
It has been acknowledged that increasing economic activity
in the Mexican Northern states and decreasing economic activity in the largest
cities has characterized the recent regional change in Mexico. What has been
the impact of this regional change in the national and regional productivity
performance?. In this article, after the author identifies and analyzes the
growth patterns of the regional manufacture for the period 1970-1993, he
explores the implicatiosn of the regional change on the national productivity
performance. In particular, this article concludes that if well the regional
change can be considered in static terms, because it reflects minimization of
transport costs and exploitation of increasing internal returns to scale, this
spatial reallocation of the economic activity could not be considered efficient
in dynamic terms, because regions that have shown higher employement growth are
not those that show the higher producitivity growth.
I. INTRODUCTION
It has been acknowledged that the recent regional change in
Mexico can be described as one where economic activity increases in the
northern states and decreases in the largest cities but, to my best knowledge,
there has been no solid empirical analysis and evaluation of this regional
change on the national and regional productivity growth. In this paper, after
the author identifies and analyzes the growth patterns of the regional
manufacturing for the period 1970-1993, the author explores the implications of
this regional change on the manufacturing productivity growth in Mexico. In
particular, this article concludes that if the regional change can be
considered efficient in static, short run economics because it reflects
minimizing of transport costs and exploitation of increasing internal returns
to scale (see Livas and Krugman, 1992), this spatial reallocation of economic
activity could not be considered efficient in a dynamic, long run economics;
regions that have shown higher growth rates in terms of employment are not
those that have shown higher growth rates in productivity.
The analysis developed in this paper is particularly
relevant since most of productivity analyses are at firms or sector levels but
no at spatial level. This is even more significant if we take in account that
new economic growth theories have noted that spatial dispersion of
technological externalities are relevant in explaining economic growth. In
particular, these theories have concluded that economic externalities generated
by endogenous growth factors, such as education, public infrastructure,
learning by doing, and knowledge spillover, among others factors, are relevant
as economic growth factors. In this way, this research can be seen as a
preliminary approach to the analysis of economic growth that suggests
endogenous growth factors in Mexican regional economic growth.
In this article, using the Mexican manufacturing census,the
author firstly presents an analysis of employment and output by regions for the
period 1970-1993. In this part, the author follows an 'ad hoc' regionalization
that reflects the industrialization patterns rather than other spatial
characteristics. Secondly,the author presents an analysis of productivity
growth by regions, based on two productivity indicators, output per worker and
total factor productivity (TFP). To my best knowledge, this is the first time
an analysis of productivity sources by regions is presented. Finally, in the
conclusion,the author evaluates the implications on the productivity
performance of the recent regional change in the Mexican manufacturing
productivity growth and present some explications for the observed pattern of
regional productivity growth.
II. RECENT REGIONAL CHANGE IN MEXICO.
In this part, first, the author presents a regionalization
that illustrates the dramatic changes in output and labor growth among regions
in the recent period in order to show more clearly the characteristics of the
recent regional change. And, in a second part, based on my 'ad hoc'
regionalization, the author identifies the characteristics of the recent
regional change in the manufacture.
A. Regionalization Proposal.
It has been acknowledged that the recent regional change in
Mexico, since 1980, can be described as one where economic activity increases
in northern states and decreases in the largest cities. A long list of
researchers1 have documented this trend that has become common
knowledge among regional specialists in Mexico. In this article, because
analysis based on conventional regionalizations has been made (see my footnote
1),the author proposes an 'ad hoc' regionalization that features dramaticaly
the regional change of economic activity. This regionalization presents, on one
hand, the participation of the three largest cities in the national output and
employment, and, on the another hand, the participation of the northern states.
Both 'regions' let us observe the relevant locational change in economic
activity since they cover about 60 or 70 percent of the total employment and
about 80 or 90 percent of the output. The rest of the states are classified as
Central, West-Central, and Rest of the Country regions, according to
industrialization and location patterns that, as we will see later, also
present clear differences in economic performance. In particular, states are
classified as follow:
a) The states of Distrito Federal, Jalisco, Mexico State,
and Nuevo Leon are classified as the Largest Cities Region. These states
are characterized by manufacturing activity that is consolidated under the
import substitution industrialization and that features the highest levels of
output per worker in the national manufacture. They also concentrated the
economic growth rates since 1950 and are the locus of the three largest
industrialized cities in the country, Ciudad de Mexico, Guadalajara and
Monterrey.
b) Northern Region includes the states of Baja
California, Coahuila, Chihuahua, Sonora, and Tamaulipas. Manufacturing in this
region was promoted by the Export Maquiladora Program since the 1960's and has
been specially encouraged under the trade liberalization strategy. Tax
subsidies, transport cost advantage and agglomeration economies with the
American southern states are the growth base for this region.
c) A third and fourth region identify the performance of
two regions of accelerated industrialization outside the Largest Cities and
Northern regions. They are states that have steadily increasing their
participation in the national manufactures since the 60's (see Vleugels, 1990).
In this 'newly industrialized periphery',the author includes as Central Region,
the states of Hidalgo, Morelos, Puebla, Queretaro y Tlaxcala; and as West-Central Region, the states of Aguascalientes, Guanajuato, Michoacan and San Luis
Potosi. The Central and West Central regions let us, in my opinion, identify
states that, besides their geographic location, take their industrialization
off under different initiatives, with the Mexico City decentralization program
for the Central region and for West Central region under a spontaneous
initiative, that is not related to a particular government or business
initiative.
B. Regional Change in the Manufacture.
Based on my 'ad hoc' regionalization,the author identifies
the characteristics of the recent regional change in the manufacture in tables
1 and 2. These tables are presented in terms of regional participation of each
region in relation to the national total whereas the objective of the
presentation is to identify the comparative performance of each region. In that
way, the author 'isolates' the effects that can be attributed to the changes in
national performance that is common to greater or less degree to all regions.
In terms of employment, in table 1 the author observes a
significant loss in the share of Largest Cities in national employment. Since
1970, this share goes from 59.73 to 43.34 percent in 1993. Because the author
is talking about changes in percent share,the author observes that a decrement
(increment) in their participation out of the national level is implying a
growth rate under (above) the national average rate. In the same table 1,the
author observes that my North region has notedly increased its participation,
going from 11.25 to 22.23 percent for the analyzed period. For the "newly
industrialized periphery", the Central and Central-West regions, have also
increased their participation but at a lower rate than the North. 'The Rest of
the Country' region have also increased its participation. In this and further
analysis,the author omits data referent to 1980 whereas this data show changes
due more to oil boom in the Mexican economy than 'structural' trends.
In the table 2,the author shows the relative performance of
the output, measured by the added value, by region. This table show a
performance similar to that in our analysis for the employment in table 1.
This reallocation of economic activity in the Mexican
geography has been explained as result of the interaction of internal economies
of scale, agglomeration economies, transport costs, and a moving of the central
market from the largest cities to the northern states due to economic and trade
liberalization policies. ( See Livas and Krugman, 1992; Hanson, 1994). The
implications of these analyses can be better understood if it is thought in
terms of a change in economic strategy, from one based on import substitution
to one based on trade liberalization. Under import substitution
industrialization, because the trade protection of the national manufacturing,
the central market2 was the internal market, that is where the
population is located, the largest cities in the country. During the
industrialization process there was created a feedback between population and
industrial location that resulted in concentration of the industry in the
largest cities. This situation which is widely documented in the literature on
economic development is recently explained by Livas and Krugman (1992) in terms
of internal economies of scale whereas firms look for producing for the
internal market and taking advantage of minimization of transport cost and
agglomeration economies.
But, what will be the regional location pattern under trade
liberalization?. Livas and Krugman (1992) suggest a moving of the firms from
the old central market, the largest cities, to the new central market, the
United States as they are the main trade partner to Mexico. The implications in
terms of industrial locations are a moving of firms towards the cities
geographically closed to the United States where these firms will take
advantage of economies of scale whereas firms produce for both countries from
one location. Then, in the northern cities, firms minimize transport cost and
after a while, they will create agglomeration economies which will encourage
even more the attraction of economic activity towards the northern region.
If, in terms of short term economic efficiency, this
reallocation of the economic activity can be explained as a result of the
optimizing decisions by firms, in the next part of this article the author
describes what is the impact of this reallocation on economic growth and, in
particular, on the productivity growth that, in the long run, determines the
possibility of economic and social development for regions.
III. PATTERNS OF PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH IN REGIONAL
MANUFACTURE.
In this part,the author describes the performance of the
manufacture productivity in a regional perspective based on two productiviy
indicators: output per worker and as total factor productivity(TFP3).
In particular,the author analyzes the level and rate of growth in productivity
measured in both indicator for the Mexican regions, as they were classified in
my 'ad hoc' regionalization.
A. The Regional Productivity Growth: Output per Worker.
In table 3 ,the author presents the dynamics of the levels
of regional productivity in relation to a national average follwing my later
regional analyisis in order to 'aisolate' the effects that can be attributed to
the changes in national performance that can be common in greater or less
degree to all regions. In this table, we can observe that the region where the
largest cities are located still maintain the highest level of productivity for
all the period. In contrast, the North region show a decrement in its level
productivity in relation to national average that goes from 0.98, in 1970, to
0.73, in 1993. The Central region mantains its level of 0.84 during the same
period. For West-Central and 'Rest of the Country' regions there are increments
in the level of productivity in relation to the national average.
Table 4 shows the productivity performance (output per
worker) by regions for periods, 1970-85, 1985-88, and 1970-93. The regional
growth rates are expressed in relation to the national productivity growth
rate. That is, for instance, a growth rate of 1.33 means that the growth rate
for that region is 33 percent higher than the national growth rate for the same
period. In that way, in table 4, the author observes that the output per worker
growth for the Largest Cities region is relatively similar to the national,
1.07 out of national growth rate. The North region has grown for all periods
below the national average rate of growth. In contrast, West-Central and Rest
of the Country regions show a significant rate of growth higher than the
national average.
A conclusion of this set of tables is the persistent
patterns of regional productivity in Mexico, since 1970 to 1993. That is,
steady economic growth in the largest cities region, negative growth in the
northern border, and accelerated growth for our West-Central and Rest of the
Country regions.
In this article, so far, the analysis on economic growth
has been based on terms of output per worker, but as it is known, the growth of
output per worker is mainly determined by the growth of capital goods available
per worker. Then, an analysis based only on output per worker is limited, in
the next part of the article, the author analyzes the economic growth and its
sources by region by means of the analysis of TFP. In my best knowledge, this
analysis have not been done for Mexican regions.
B. The Sources of Economic Growth: A Regional Perspective.
In this part of this article,the author presents an
analysis of the sources of economic growth by regions. In particular,the author
presents estimates of TFP for each region, as defined in my 'ad hoc'
regionalization, for the periods, 1970-85, 1985-1988, and for both periods,
1970-93. The author follows the conventional methodology in growth accounting
that let us identify the productivity growth as residual out of output growth
minus the weighted change in use of productive factors. In this way, TFP is
identified as the change in output that cannot be attributed to change in use
of productive factors, and that define the 'make more with less', the basic
characteristic of the economic growth. It is acknowledged that this methodology
has multiple restrictions, however, its use as conventional measure of
productivity make particularly attractive its application.
Following this methodology4, let assume that the
manufacturing output (added value) in each state is a function of capital,
labor5 and time, that are combinated by means of a state production
function. Then, the necessary conditions for the optimization equilibrium for
the state as a representative agent, and assuming constant returns to scale at
state level, imply that the output elasticities with relation to capital and
labor are equals to the participation of the each productive factor in the
total cost. Therefore, the share of capital and labor in relation to total cost
are equal to one. In that way, the growth rate of the output is expressed as
the addition of the growth rates in the amount of capital and labor, each one
weighted by their share in the total cost, and total factor productivity. This
model is developed using data from the manufacturing census for the years 1970,
1985, and 1993. The author identifies the 'total de activos fijos' as data for
capital, 'valor aggregado censal bruto' (added value) as data for output, and
'empleo promedio anual' (annual average number of workers) as data for labor5.
In relation to prices at regional level, the information in nominal prices has
been deflacted with the implicit price index for the GNP in base of 1980
prices. Therefore, it is assumed that there are no significant differences in
inflation among regions.
Tables 5, 6, 7, show my estimates of sources of growth by
region for the periods 1970-85, 1985-88, and 1970-93. In relation to the
regional variations, in table 7 that shows the period from 1970-93 we can
observe that regions that have shown a positive rate of TFP growth are the
Largest cities and Rest of the Country, our Largest cities regions is the only
that persistently along the period showed a growth rate above the national
average, see table 5 and 6. In contrast, the North region shows TFP growth
rates that persistently were under the national average. The rest of regions
show a mix performance, for instance, West-Central region showed a negative
growth of rate in TFP before 1985 and a amazing positive rate of growth in TFP
after 1985. Different performance was shown by the 'Rest of the Country' region
that obtained a TFP growth rate above of national average before 1985, but one
under the national average for later 1985, see table 5 and 6. All these changes
in productivity performance confirm in general, our previous conclusions on
regional economic performance. That is, there exists a stagnation in the
productivity growth in our Largest cities region. A negative performance in the
North and a positive performance in the 'Rest of the Country' region. A mixed
performance in West-Central and Central regions. The table 5, 6, and 7 show
this trend and let us observe that in the case of the North region, its growth
is based on capital and employment growth but not on productivity.
III CONCLUSIONS
So far, with the limitations of the data,the author expects
to have showed the broader trends in regional performance, but what are the
implications of the regional change and productivity for the Mexican economic
growth? And what explains the persistent regional dynamic in terms of
productivity?. In the next part of this article, as conclusion,the author
offers some preliminary answers to these questions. In particular, in relation
to the first question,the author evaluates the implications of the regional
change on the economic growth extending the Reynolds (1979)'s analysis to
evaluate the recent change until 1988.
The performance of regional economic growth previous to
1970's, according to Reynolds(1979) and Reynolds and Alejo (1987), was
characterized by a highest level of Gross State Product (GSP) per capita in the
Mexico City region6, medium level in North Pacific region7,
and North8 with the lowest level in the rest of the country, but the
South region9 in the 1970's due to oil boom concentrated in this
region during these years. Whereas Mexico City region was able to absorb
population and maintain its productivity level, it was observed that labor
migration from the low to high productivity regions contributed to the
productivity growth at national level, even when this contribution was
decreasing over years. Reynolds (1979), using the shift-share accounting,
identify the regional change component in 16 percent in 1940's, 11 percent in
1950's, 14 percent in 1960's, and 1 percent in 1970's. That is, at the best a
sixth or 10th out of the output per capita growth at national level can be
explained by the labor migration.
In order to evaluate how important the regional change has
been in explaining the recent manufacture growth at national level,the author
uses the same approach as Reynolds (1979). If we take in account that the
employment has grown more in the regions with the lowest level in output per
worker, the 'transference' of interregional employment has negatively
contributed to increase the national level of productivity. According my
estimates for manufacturing, if the employment growth would have increased in
same proportion in all regions, the output per worker would have been 16
percent higher than the observed one for 1985-1988. If this trend continues, as
data for 1993 shows, the persistent dynamic of the productivity disassociated
from the regions with highest employment growth rate, imply that as much as the
employment grows in the regions of lowest productivity growth rate, the
productivity in manufacture is negatively affected. Therefore, the recent
employment growth is limited in terms of productivity and also limited the role
of the manufacture in the regional economic development. Even more, the
significant increment in Mexican manufacture productivity since 1984, that have
been noted by Brown and Dominguez (1994), Elias (1992), and Weiss (1992), seems
not be encouraged by the regional change.
In relation with our initial second question, whereas the
regions with highest productivity growth maintain this performance along the
period, before and under a freer trade regimen, what seems to explain this
performance? Two hypothesis seems to be attractive in explaining the
persistence of the regional productivity patterns despise the recent regional
change.
One of these two hypothesis is related to the new
activities that are promoted under trade liberalization. In particular, that
the new activities do not promoted the use of knowledge. Rivera-Batiz and Xie
(1993) have suggested than in the case of economic integration between
countries with unequal endowment of human capital that is applied to the
production of knowledge, the integration can induce to the non-innovating
country to be a chronically non-innovating country. If the endowment of human
capital is lower, in relation to the partner, the non-innovating country is
maintained in that condition after the integration. They suggest that whereas
Mexico is the non-innovating country in the NAFTA case, such results are
applicable to the new activities to be promoted. However, it interesting to
note that if we observe the productivity in the maquiladora industry, we also
note differences in productivity among regions. Maquiladoras in Guadalajara or
Monterrey present higher productivity growth than in the Northern border cities
(Wilson, 1994).
The another hypothesis about the explaining of differences
in productivity growth among regions is about the regional characteristics that
promote the productivity in each case. This hypothesis take us to a series of
economic growth factors identified in the new growth theory, or endogenous
growth theories, such as education, learning by doing, public infrastructure,
and knowledge spillovers, among others, that are identified as externalities
that promote growth, by means of avoiding the decreasing returns to physical
capital. In this way, these endogenous growth models suggest that if endogenous
growth factors are relevant, regions that have promoted, intentionally or not,
these factors should show a better performance in economic growth. This
explanation is extended if we see the effects of this endogenous growth factors
as technological externalities and therefore, not identified by the firms in
their investment decisions, and by the same token, not having motives for
promoting those externalities. From this hypothesis, it can be inferred that
the disassociation between productivity and regional change of economic
activity does not necessarily means regional change imply lower productivity
growth, but productivity growth is not 'automatic' and related to economic
activity growth. Productivity growth is a phenomena related to specific
characteristics historically created in the regions and once identified can be
subject of public policies. In this stage of the research, the empirical
evaluation of this and the another hypothesis seem particularly attractive for
further research.
REFERENCES
* Professor, Economics Department, CUCEA, Universidad de
Guadalajara. E-mail [email protected]. This is a revision of the paper
presented at Internatinal Conference on Economic Integration and
Transformation, York University-The Athenian Policy Forum Inc., and seminars in
University of Notre Dame and Universidad de Guadalajara. The author gratefully
acknowledges the financial support of the Kellogg Institute and Graduate
School, University of Notre Dame during my doctoral student years and the Flora
and William Hewlett Foundation in my professional years.
1 For a survey, see Scott (1982), Quintanilla (1987),
Hanson (1994), and Polese and Pérez Mendoza (1995).
2 In this context, central market should be understood as
the place where the principal sources of demand, final and intermediate, are
located, that is where the most of the consumer and suppliers are located.
3 Total factor productivity (TFP) is conventionaly defined
as the residual out of the output growth minus the increment in the use and
quality of labor and capital, both weighted by their share in the added value.
Then, TFP is identified as the technological change.
4 For the applicability of this methodology at regional
level, see Moomaw and Williams (1991).
5 The methodology in growth accounting suggests the use of
data on worker-hour, but because these data is no available, I use a 'proxy'
the number of workers. That is assumed that all workers works the same number
of hours.
6 Distrito Federal and Mexico state.
7 Baja California Norte, Baja California Sur, Nayarit,
Sinaloa, and Sonora.
8 Coahuila, Chihuahua, Durango, Nuevo León, San Luis
Potosí, Tamaulipas, and Zacatecas.
9 South region includes the rest of the country.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Brown, Flor, and Lilia Dominguez, "The Dynamics of
Productivity Performance in Mexican Manufacturing, 1984-90," The Developing
Economies, XXXII:3, 1994, 279-298.
Elias, Victor J.,Sources of Growth: A Study of Seven Latin
American Economies, ICS Press. "A joint research project of the
Fundacion del Tucuman y The International Center for Economic Growth",San
Francisco, CA., 1992
Hanson, Gordon, Regional Adjustment to Trade Liberalization,
National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper # 4713, Cambridge, MA,
1994.
Livas Elizondo, Raul and Paul R. Krugman,Trade Policy and
the Thirld World Metropolis, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Working Paper # 4238, Cambridge, MA.,1994,
Moomaw, Ronald L. and M. Willians, "Total Factor
Productivity Growth in Manufacturing: Further Evidence from the States." Journal
of Regional Science, 31:1, 1991, 17-34.
Polese, Mario y S. Pérez Mendoza,
"Integración Económica Norteamericana y cambio regional en
México," Comercio Exterior, 45:2, 1995, 132-138.
Quintanilla, Ernesto, "Comportamiento regional del
crecimiento industrial en México," Comercio Exterior, 37:7, 1987
570-574.
Reynolds, Clark, "A Shift-Share Analysis of Regional and
Sectoral Productiviy Growth in Contemporary México," Draft.
International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Austria, 1979.
Reynolds, Clark and F.J. Alejo, "Effects of Intersectoral
Labor Shifts on Productivity Growth: México's Experience and
Implications for the United States," Indian Journal of Industrial Relations,
23:2,1987,158-187.
Rivera-Batiz, Luis A. y D. Xie, "Integration among
Unequals," Regional Science and Urban Economics, 23:2, 1993, 337-354.
Scott, Ian, Urban Spatial Development in Mexico,
Hopkins university Press, Baltimore, 1982.
Vleugels, Rene M.P. 1990. Industrialization and Secondary
Cities in Central México. Verlag breitenbach Publishers,
Saarbrucken-Fort Lauderdale, Fl., 1990.
Weiss, John, "Trade Policy Reform and Performance in
Manufaturting: México 1975-1988," Journal of Development Studies,
29:1, 1992, 1-23.
Wilson, Patricia, Exports and Local Development: Mexico's
New Maquiladoras, University of Texas, Austin, TX., 1992.
TABLE 1
EMPLOYMENT SHARE BY REGIONS
MEXICAN MANUFACTURING : 1970-1993
REGIONS |
1970 |
1980 |
1985 |
1988 |
1993 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
LARGEST_C. |
59.73 |
59.48 |
53.90 |
47.78 |
43.34 |
NORTH |
11.25 |
8.11 |
15.07 |
19.87 |
22.23 |
CENTRAL |
7.98 |
8.26 |
9.97 |
9.69 |
10.80 |
WEST-C. |
7.82 |
6.23 |
8.89 |
9.91 |
10.42 |
REST_OF_THE_C. |
13.20 |
17.91 |
12.16 |
12.74 |
13.19 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
TOTAL |
100.00 |
100.00 |
100.00 |
100.00 |
100.00 |
Source: Industrial census, Mexico.
TABLE 2
OUTUPUT SHARE BY REGIONS
MEXICAN MANUFACTURING: 1970-1993
REGIONS
|
1970
|
1980
|
1985
|
1988
|
1993
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
LARGEST_C.
|
68.6
|
50.3
|
55.1
|
54.2
|
52.12
|
NORTH
|
11.1
|
8.7
|
13.6
|
15.9
|
16.29
|
CENTRAL
|
6.7
|
6.6
|
11.2
|
11.1
|
9.09
|
WEST-C.
|
4.5
|
3.3
|
6.1
|
8.5
|
8.96
|
REST_OF_THE_C.
|
8.9
|
30.9
|
13.8
|
10.2
|
13.52
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
TOTAL
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
100.0
|
Source: Same TABLE 1.
TABLE 3
COMPARATIVE OUTPUT PER WORKER BY REGIONS
NACIONAL LEVEL = 1)
MEXICO: 1970-1993
REGIONS
|
1970
|
1980
|
1985
|
1988
|
1993
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
LARGEST_C.
|
1.14
|
0.84
|
1.02
|
1.13
|
1.20
|
NORTH
|
0.98
|
1.08
|
0.90
|
0.80
|
0.73
|
CENTRAL
|
0.84
|
0.80
|
1.12
|
1.14
|
0.84
|
WEST-C.
|
0.57
|
0.52
|
0.69
|
0.86
|
0.85
|
REST_OF_THE_C.
|
0.67
|
1.72
|
1.13
|
0.80
|
1.02
|
Thousand of pesos
of 1980
|
264
|
328
|
255
|
318
|
289
|
TOTAL
|
1.00
|
1.00
|
1.00
|
1.00
|
1.00
|
Source: Same TABLE 2.
TABLE 4
COMPARATIVE GROWTH RATE OF OUTPUT PER WORKER BY
REGIONS
NATIONAL GROWTH RATES = 1)
MEXICO: 1970-1993
REGION
|
1970-1985
|
1985-88
|
1970-93
|
|
|
|
|
LARGEST_C.
|
0.88
|
1.10
|
1.07
|
NORTH
|
0.91
|
0.88
|
0.72
|
CENTRAL
|
1.33
|
1.01
|
1.03
|
WEST-C.
|
1.21
|
1.23
|
1.40
|
REST_OF_THE_C.
|
1.69
|
0.70
|
1.51
|
|
|
|
|
TOTAL
|
1.00
|
1.00
|
1.00
|
Source: Industrial census, various years.
TABLE 5
SOURCES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH BY REGION
MEXICO: 1970-1985
(Annual average growth rates)
Producto
|
LARGEST C.
|
NORTH
|
CENTRAL
|
WEST-C.
|
R_DE_C.
|
TOTAL
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Output(VACB)
|
1.56
|
4.50
|
6.59
|
5.27
|
6.10
|
3.06
|
Capital
|
2.47
|
4.59
|
5.26
|
8.72
|
5.40
|
3.80
|
Labor
|
1.09
|
2.06
|
1.92
|
1.70
|
0.95
|
1.33
|
TFP
|
-2.0
|
-2.15
|
-0.59
|
-5.15
|
-0.25
|
-2.07
|
Source: My own calculations in base of industrial
census.
TABLE 6
SOURCES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH BY REGION
MEXICO: 1985-1988
(Annual average growth rates)
Producto
|
LARGEST_C.
|
NORTH
|
CENTRAL
|
WEST-C.
|
R_DE_C.
|
TOTAL
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Output (VACB)
|
7.89
|
14.21
|
8.00
|
20.5
|
-2.04
|
8.29
|
Capital
|
-4.3
|
5.66
|
-0.89
|
-0.04
|
6.49
|
-0.21
|
Labor
|
-1.15
|
3.99
|
0.11
|
1.6
|
0.70
|
0.23
|
TFP
|
13.34
|
4.56
|
8.78
|
18.94
|
-9.23
|
7.85
|
Source: Same table 5.
TABLE 7
SOURCES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH BY REGION
MEXICO: 1970-1993
(Annual mean growth rates)
Producto
|
LARGEST_C.
|
NORTH
|
CENTRAL
|
WEST-C.
|
R_DE_C.
|
TOTAL
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Output(VACB)
|
2.49
|
5.67
|
5.37
|
6.74
|
5.80
|
3.71
|
Capital
|
1.39
|
2.73
|
3.44
|
5.92
|
3.63
|
2.53
|
Labor
|
0.68
|
3.02
|
1.96
|
1.84
|
1.22
|
1.31
|
TFP
|
0.42
|
-0.08
|
-0.03
|
-1.02
|
0.94
|
-0.13
|
Source: Same table 5.
|