Mexico and the World
Vol. 2, No 4 (Fall 1997)
http://www.profmex.org/mexicoandtheworld/volume2/4fall97/clarkfinal998.html
Integrating Cities
and Regions: North America Faces Globalization
Edited by James W. Wilkie and Clint E. Smith
Associate Editor: Francisco Gil-White
Conclusions and Implications for Policy and Research
Clark W. Reynolds
Stanford University
I. Introduction: This volume provides dramatic evidence that
the impact of global economic liberalization cannot be understood without
focusing on specific regions, industries, and social groups at particular times
and places. So unbalanced and
asymmetrical is the current process of international economic
integration--involving major restructuring of industries, households, and
institutions--that each locality has its own path. Such differences tend to be lost in national averages. The interaction of these separate paths of
development leads to a process of structural change that goes beyond general
models based on "first-best” assumptions. Such models tend to hypothesize cost-less movements from one
"equilibrium" to another, and implicitly assume that winners will
compensate losers. The preceding
chapters illustrate the kind of practical problems that besiege each locality
day by day. They show the need for new
policies and decisions that will make the process of integration workable. This comes as no surprise to decision-makers
at the local level. But where systems
interact, local policies must be coordinated with national and international
decisions to avoid unexpectedly chaotic results. This calls for an intervening analysis to provide a framework in
which parts can be seen in terms of the whole. Approaches are called for in
which the good of the whole only can be achieved by accommodating the interests
of the few.
The goal of this volume is
to go beyond the presentation and testing of general hypotheses about
integration to take an iterative approach to the impact of globalization by
looking at selected regions and identifying key issues that call for attention. Whether one is concerned with general
policies or specific regional problems, it is hoped that the common orientation
used in these case studies as well as their particular findings will be useful. Some of the salient findings force a
widening of the scope of future analysis, as well as more in-depth examination
of particular problems, issues that are addressed in this introductory
chapter. The approach is to provide a
new framework to accommodate regional disparities in order to address the problems
which arise not only from inertial demographic forces, but from changing
resource endowments, technology, and tastes, as well as the external forces of
economic, social, and technological, change. The model in chapter 1 on the "political economy of open
regionalism" provides a common perspective—one which views each region as
an open developing economy needing to foster cooperation among its member
units. But each case study that follows
reveals the complexity of the process of growth with structural change caused
in part by economic liberalization and integration. That process goes well beyond the dimensions of the introductory
model, opening up new avenues for exploration as well as illustrating the need
for sharper analysis of specific relationships in the next stage of research.
[1]
The three North American
economies of NAFTA offer almost too wide universe from which to take the first
samples.
[2]
The regions selected for observation
represent three general categories: major metropolitan areas (New York, Mexico City, and Toronto); border
regions north and south (Cascadian; San Diego/Tijuana; Arizona/Sonora); and
lagging regions (Oaxaca; Newfoundland.) This chapter examines the key findings of each of the cases in that
order. Perhaps the first and most important finding, true of all cases, is that
the direct impact of trade and economic liberalization is swamped by the
endogenous forces of demographic change, macroeconomic cycles, and shifting
technologies (which would evolve with or without "globalization" but
which are speeded up by economic integration.)
But there is a second
finding, sharply evidenced by exchange rate” meltdowns" like the Mexican
peso crisis of 1994/95. The new
technologies have integrated financial markets even faster than those for goods
and (non-financial) services. This
sudden "silent" integration of financial markets carries with it
consequences for real trade and investment. Open international markets impose iron laws on monetary and fiscal
policy and limit the degrees of freedom of macroeconomic decision-makers. Even wage policy is vulnerable to more fluid
trade and migration patterns. Hence the
resulting structural changes in production and employment reflect more flexible
real and financial markets rather than government fiat. In fact, decision-makers find themselves
limited by international events in today's world, even at the cost of lost
autonomy, autarchy, monopoly, and monophony power. They are forced to accept as given the exogenous forces which
blow, like trade winds, beyond the action of any principality or power. Meanwhile it islet to regional
decision-makers to deal with the local impact of national policies on specific
firms, industries, and income groups. The irony of globalization is that development economic decision-making
has been forced to shift from the national to testate and local level and to
sub-regional institutions.
The first step is to draw
back from easy generalizations and focusing on specific persons and
places—while at the same time remaining committed to the overall goal which is
to achieve "gains from trade, finance, and development” The goal of policy
is to ensure that those gains are as consistent as possible with social equity
and environmental sustainability. This
is particularly important for marginalized sub-regions, income groups, and
economic activities which are either left behind in the process or
adversely-affected by globalization. The evidence indicates that even though the process of evolution may be
prolonged by astute fiscal transfers and growth-oriented public and private
sector support and remittances, most will eventually need to transform or
die. In the case where the needed
transformation calls for resources that can only be mobilized in the public
domain—where the funding of externalities is resistant to the profit motive—new
incentives and patterns of public/private sector cooperation (joint ventures)
may well be needed. This appears to be
essential to sustain growth with equity even for the most privileged subregions,
including those on the forefront of the new technologies such as Silicon
Valley.
Some generalizations may be
made about the chapters. They are
introductory in nature, holistic, and heavily descriptive. The choice of regions to be studied was more
arbitrary than scientific, tending to make use of research groups that were
already committed to analysis of the area concerned (so as to take advantage of
their enormous accumulation of knowledge, skill, and insights into regional
peculiarities yet with a global vision), indicating the need to go further in
the next phase and to add regions such as the Texas/Mexico border region; a
Midwestern U.S. urban area; a southeastern U.S. region; one of the western
Canadian provinces (such as Alberta); more leading and lagging regions from
Mexico, not to mention cases from the broader Caribbean Basin and South
America. In addition, it is important
to go beyond this hemisphere for comparison and contrast with the sub-regional
impact of integration in Europe, Asia, the Near East, and Africa.
Some localities seem to be
more natural candidates for integration than others. This is not discussed in the chapters but there seems to be a
pattern in which complementarities among component sub-units plus agglomeration
economies from clustering of similar activities matter to the success of the
integration process. The Ricardian
international trade concept of comparative advantage suggests that under
certain conditions all regions gain by trade. But if one allows factor movements as well as free exchange of goods and
services it is quite possible to envision some locales (generally remote,
underdeveloped, and with scarce resources) which may lose both labor and
capital and return to a state of wilderness. There is also no evidence that all regions experience the same gains
from trade, and some may even retrogress once all barriers to exchange
(including those affecting migration and investment) are lowered. The assumption that all regions will grow
and prosper with integration is not supported by the evidence to date—even
among the cases in this volume.
In short, there is a lack of
in-depth analysis of economic and social integration which results from the
removal of barriers to exchange (i.e. movement toward "full exchange"
of all goods and factors). But some of
the chapters make important steps in the direction of the role of trade in
their recent history. Most noteworthy
in this regard are the studies of Toronto (which explicitly tests the relative
importance of trade, technology, and domestic demand and finds that trade,
while important, is in third place); New York (which deals with leading and
lagging sectors in trade and their importance for both employment and fiscal
stability); and Mexico City (which shows how the shift from import-competing
production to serve a captive domestic market, to trade and investment
liberalization, has dramatically impacted local manufacturing and reduced
incentives to invest in the metropolis.) All of the studies touch on the restructuring that trade liberalization
has caused, and especially those of the border regions—but here again the force
of change is less that of intraregional exchange than of new patterns of
competition with the rest of the world in which the region is required to participate.
Hence, it is necessary to go
beyond the export-led growth model to one which includes attention to domestic
demand and the related pattern of income distribution—both of which are
affected by regional policy in response to national liberalization
measures. This includes the creation of
infrastructure, skill formation, and investment incentives. The tightness or slackness of local labor
markets will be impacted by access to low-priced labor-intensive imports which
compete with regional production. Local
job markets reflects not only the decline of less-competitive sectors (and
associated layoffs), but also job-creation in newly competitive activities,
lagged patterns of demographic growth (especially important in Mexico, given
its earlier high fertility rates), and migration trends (especially relevant to
border regions north and south and to major metropolitan areas—which act as
magnets for those in search of improved levels of living, and who feel
themselves left behind by structural changes and dislocations in their place of
origin Most of the chapters ask whether
or not it is possible to stimulate domestic demand in a specific locale and to
increase exports to the rest of the domestic economy and abroad. Sub-regional development policies must be
undertaken in a non-inflationary manner, subject to the iron laws of
macroeconomic policy under globalization.
One of the subjects
requiring much more attention in future research is the role of finance as a
vehicle for integration on a region-by-region basis. In all three countries capital markets have experienced increased
national integration, liberalization, and globalization. To what extent does today's new capital
market openness push transactions to the short end, especially in markets which
are subject to greater risk from inflation, exchange rated evaluation, and
other elements of instability (i.e. "emerging markets") that cause
long-term borrowing to face extremely high real interest rates by any
reasonable forecast? This could favor
consumption-based lending (e.g. credit cards and other forms of consumer
credit) over investment. Re-privatization and internationalization of the banking system in
Mexico in the 1990s has already produced a tendency to move financial capital
toward urban centers and away from regional financial institutions, tending to
work against investment lending in outlying areas (and especially in lagging
regions) although this remains to be studied in more detail. In principle the process of financial
liberalization should broaden the degrees of freedom for trade and investment
funding. It should even permit regions
with greater growth potential to be "net borrowers" from the rest of
the nation and abroad, raising what might be called "the region's current
account deficit" be providing resources for increased investment and
export expansion (as capital flows into the region in response to higher
returns than elsewhere.)
Increased freedom of
financial flows among regions should also make available working capital and investment
in startups in response to new profit-making opportunities. This calls for what might be termed a
"regional venture capital" response. However the institution of venture capital and related
risk-taking tends to be concentrated in high-tech areas rather than in emerging
market economies. For the latter,
financial markets tend to be especially incomplete or unresponsive to the needs
of small investors. They tend to have
less collateral; more need for managerial and technical assistance, and impose
higher transaction costs per unit of lending than wealthier borrowers in more
developed regions. In this case
positive externalities exist for regional policies that would facilitate
financial market completion in particular localities, including access to
investment in physical and human capital. There is an important role for the formation of sub-regional
institutions both public and private that could bring about a broader
distribution of the gains from growth.
The studies show that
changes in the structure of economies matter importantly to their subsequent
paths of growth and distribution. Dynamic comparative advantage can be much different from the static
competitiveness of a region. This is
why it is so important for decision-makers to look ahead and plan for
change. The more open the economy, the
more crucial it is to engage in some aspects of sub-regional planning, as
decision-making on specific investments shifts from the national to the
regional level, and as regions find themselves more rather than less-integrated
with international markets. The role of
sub-regional planning is less that of predetermining growth and setting targets
and more that of exploring realistic options for structural change, as well as
providing facilitating measures to maximize the locality's competitiveness and
social well-being—as national and global environments change. The extent to which structural changes are
due to new technologies, falling transport and communication costs, and
institutional lowering of barriers to exchange remains to be studied on a
region by region basis. The chapters
refer to the importance of such factors, but in most cases there has not been
the opportunity to go beyond observations—highly suggestive as they are.
Staples-based growth has
been important to many regions at the outset of development (e.g. Arizona/Sonora; Cascadian), but for
others growth has-been stimulated by manufacturing and services including those
activities with new links to the rest of the world such as the NAFTA and
Pacific Rim. San Diego/Tijuana,
Toronto, and New York are all responding to the new stimuli from globalization
even as they undergo restructuring from older patterns of trade and investment. However it has not been possible in most of
the studies to spell out the mechanisms involved in the new patterns of trade
and development, although in some—as we have seen—their consequences for
employment and urban growth have been presented.
Demographic and
demo-economic patterns of change, including migration, are not developed in
terms of causality, although the importance of changing demographic structures
to differences in regional growth paths is evident in the results to date. New immigration tends to favor large urban
areas (Toronto, Mexico City, New York) while at the same time all three are
experiencing a movement of middle and upper income groups to the suburbs. This works against distributional policies
that depend on fiscal transfers, education, and infrastructure support. On the other hand, there is increased
migration from less to more-rapidly developing sub-regions.
Dissimilar approaches in
each chapter limit their potential for comparison in this first phase of
analysis. This was almost assured by
the need to "piggy-back" the research for this volume on work already
underway by different groups in different regions—owing to budgetary
limitations and the step by step requirement for regional analysis that begins
with scenario-building. Moreover, the
lack of comparable data sets across all regions was a limiting factor in direct
comparisons. As it is, the high quality
of personnel involved, their disciplinary heterogeneity, and their unusual
commitment to the project made it a wise choice to draw from their expertise
and to take a wider approach at the outset despite the limitations. As a result, what had initially been
construed as a single project opens up an area that calls for much additional
follow-up. It is hoped that there will
be second phase to this research, intended to focus on specific issues within a
holistic analytical framework beginning with the elements in chapter one, as
modified by the findings of the subsequent chapters and developments in what
might be called the "new regionalism" in global perspective. This will ensure a more systematic
comparative approach leading to a better understanding of the socio-economic
consequences of regional integration and their policy implications in today's
world.
II. Key
Points from the Case Study Chapters:
Major Metropolitan Areas
New
York Metropolitan Area:
The
authors have sketched an interactive and inclusive portrait of a city in flux,
and the challenges that poses to local and regional governments, the
surrounding state administrations, and the federal government. Some of the issues raised (echoing those
from the studies of Mexico City and Toronto) are:
(a) What defines an economic region?
(b) How much urban growth (or decline) is
desirable?
(c) How much infrastructure is needed
(including maintenances well as new installations)?
(d) How much responsibility is attributable to the public or
private sectors?
(e) How much fiscal burden should be
placed on which groups or locales?
(f) What is the optimal level of urban
indebtedness?
(g) How does one determine the political mix of responsibility
for metropolitan budgetary stability: Federal/state/regional/local (how much
decentralization of power)?
It
should be noted that for a regional economy which includes several local and
state jurisdictions, there is no single constituency or set of institutions in
which to resolve these issues. Their resolution would tend to rely on political
decision-making that affects the economy of the entire region though in
different ways for different subregions.
[3]
With globalization and economic liberalization,
the conditions of supply and demand are continually changing—and the pace of
change increases as economies face increased international competition and the
impact of today's accelerating technologies. Integration offers new "gains
(and losses) from trade" calling for rapid responses that are hampered by
outmoded barriers to trade and investment. Globalization sharpens the opportunity cost of market distortions
imposed to satisfy particular interests (including restraints on trade,
migration, and employment) by hitting at the bottom line and by taking away
jobs and tax revenues. Integration
with liberalization is usually assumed to reduce the scope for directly
unproductive "rent seeking" and restraints on trade by those who are
forced to share power with those from outside the region. But the liberalization process may also open
the door to new forces of monopoly and monopsony power that must now be
addressed in a more complex environment involving broader constituencies that
cut across state and national boundaries. The New York Metropolitan Area study raises such considerations and
opens up issues that goes well beyond those presented in the "model"
of chapter one.
Always
a city of immigrants, today the population of NYC is almost one-fifth foreign-born. This sounds like San Diego (and to some
extent Toronto.) Located on the trade
routes of the international labor market and offering a large pool of actual
(if not potential) jobs, plus networking of successive migrant households,
these metropolitan areas characterize the "new demography" of
international population flows from emerging markets to advanced industrial
destinations, brought about by both "push" as well as "pull
factors.” These include accelerated population growth, inadequate resources,
and the lack of economic opportunity in sending areas, as well as falling
travel costs, improved communications, and the de facto "opening" of
labor markets in receiving areas to all comers. The process of attraction is driven by relentless competition
among enterprises confronted with global cost reductions, price declines, and
challenges from outsourcing. However
even for profitable enterprises, it reflects new opportunities to take
advantage of softer labor markets by replacing higher with lower-wage employees
(including temporaries) for similar jobs, in order to lower the wage share of
value added as raise the return on capital. It also indicates weakening barriers to entry (on racial, ethnic, or
union lines) and greater responsiveness of firms to opportunities to pay low
entry-level wages, even in the previous bastions of labor power such as Mexico,
New York, and Toronto.
Not surprisingly the
structural changes that this introduces, in terms of reduced labor welfare and
bargaining power, leads to major opposition to economic opening from unions and
populist politicians on all sides of the political spectrum. The need to be
responsive to present voters, while at the same time attempting to attract new
investment and to keep old firms from leaving or outsourcing jobs, creates
apolitical-economic challenge for urban governments that is increased as the
economic space of the core cities expands into the suburbs. Major cities struggle to offer tax breaks
and other incentives to investors, even as they are pressed to fund the rising
cost of social services and infrastructure out of a shrinking tax base--while
more affluent citizens move to the suburbs and footloose industries seek lower
tax havens. While this is nothing new,
harkening back to the competition between New York and New Jersey in the past
century, and to the hollowing of center cities after World War II, it is
exacerbated by the changes introduced by the new technologies and greater
flexibility of international trade and investment.
In
New York the authors identify five major industries that are experiencing
economic concentration--and in some cases relocation--accompanied by job loss
in the area particularly in the inner-city core for a number of large firms. Even in cases where the region has a global
comparative advantage (e.g. banking and financial services), employment is
being cut by automation and mergers. The fact that the region has had relatively high wages even by U.S.
standards has hurt its competitive advantage in labor-intensive industries such
as textiles and garments, so that between 1989 and the end of 1995 the New York
region experienced the work force. While levels of
personal income which showed earlier declines seem to be recovering a bit—along
with the absolute number of jobs—New York appears to be an example of” downward
convergence" in the lower echelons of the labor market in comparison with
other regions of North America.
In
New York "export-led growth" has been generated by four main
sectors:(1) finance, insurance, and real estate (FIRE); (2) culture and media;
(3)tourism and recreation; and (4) computer-related activities. The city reveals a growing "computer
intelligentsia," according to the authors, with locales such as SOHO now
being called "Silicon Alley." This is associated with a shift in the demographic structure in which
more long-standing groups are being replaced with younger persons and new waves
of immigration. A new "computer
intelligentsia" is forming. But
the shift toward more "high tech" activities is putting severe
demands on the area's infrastructure, calling for major expenditures in new
technologies, electronic networking, and education of a work force capable of
handling the evolving demands of the computer age. This affects every area of employment.
Hence the positive benefits
from new export expansion carry with them major costs, many of which are
externalities that the public sector is best-equipped to finance. Yet, as we
have seen, the creation of fiscal incentives for new enterprises, facing
increased competition from globalization, cuts into the tax base. Meanwhile increased pressure for
entitlements for an aging resident population, exacerbated by rising unit costs
of health care and social services, increases the need for government
expenditures. All of these forces work
against budgetary balance, even as globalization forces fiscal prudence on
harried urban administrations. For all
practical purposes metropolitan New York represents two metropolis, one
consisting of a more youthful, growing, high tech and immigrant-oriented
potential growth pole—and the other a sinecure for its aging population and
under-skilled minorities. These groups
that compete with each other using their respective political voices. Many older residents and less-fortunate
newcomers demand entitlements and a growing share of public expenditures, while
business, the affluent, and younger groups of skilled workers push for fiscal
conservatism. Meanwhile, the rising
interest costs of debt service, reflecting the growing budgetary gap of recent
years, has eaten into the city’s revenue base.
Increasing fiscal problems
hold for Mexico City and Toronto as well and seems to be a generalized
phenomenon of urbanization in the new era of globalization. As openness and integration lead to downward
wage and income convergence in the job market (for all but those at the top end
of the skill ladder), pressures increase for tax relief and localized
entitlements. Yet the new technologies
and trade patterns call for costly modernization and expansion of
infrastructure. Politics have tended to
polarize, changing party constituencies and alliances—and attempts to deal with
the problem seem to make things worse by encouraging the flight of many
industries to other locations which offer lower taxes, lower wages, and lower
costs of infrastructure-including maintenance and upgrading. To the extent that major cities have
over-expanded, this transition may reflect a favorable element of diffusion
(the spreading of income and productivity to a broader social and sub-regional
base)—but if this occurs at the expense of rising poverty, lower quality of
life, and increased insecurity for those remaining in the urban core areas, the
cost of diffusion is clearly "downward convergence."
The New York study is
carefully and comprehensively researched. It boldly illuminates problems facing the largest urban complex in the
United States, and calls attention to similar issues in the two other cities of
this study, Mexico City and Toronto, and on major urban entrepots around the
world enjoy benefits and bear costs of globalization. Here structural change has been overwhelming, altering patterns
of demographic growth, widening income gaps, forcing the relocation or demise
of many industries, and giving new life
to activities that service the growth of international markets including finance, merchandising, and the media. In the process, the population of New York City has been transformed,
adding an increasing share of Hispanics, Asian, and Eastern Europeans, while
the traditional white Anglo population is moving to the suburbs, to the South,
and to the West. The city's black population,
which came up from the South during and after World War II, is now reversing
its flow as the quality of life elsewhere begins to outstrip that of the
metropolis.
It
should be noted that there is no single arena in which to resolve these issues,
which are political-economic in nature, and differ from region to region. Integration changes the conditions of supply
and demand and offers new "gains from trade"(exchange), revealing the
opportunity cost of market distortions. But it also opens the door to the possibility of new restraints on trade
as more powerful forces from elsewhere are able to integrate with local
activities and even move outside of the region or threaten to do so unless they
are offered better conditions. To some
extent the New York experience appears to present new opportunities for
non-competitive behavior, raising issues that go well beyond the regional
"model" of chapter one.
Five
major industries are experiencing economic concentration and in some cases
relocation for a number of large firms. This has accompanied a loss of jobs in the area and particularly in the
inner-city core. Even in cases where
the region has a comparative advantage (e.g. banking and financial services)
jobs are being lost to automation and mergers. The region has had relatively higher wages—and this is hurting its
competitive advantage in labor-intensive activities so that between 1989 and
the end of 1995 the New York region had the worst job loss since the Great
Depression. The region's share in national
employment is shrinking (as with Mexico City)—yet there has been net job
growth. But there is a major shift to
new lower-paid and less-skilled employment in the services and in small and
medium enterprises of the private sector, vis a vis larger firms and the
government.
The
chapter on New York provides detailed information on the changing patterns of
production, employment, trade, fiscal policy, and infrastructure. It weaves together these trends, indicating
that there will be an increasing need for region-wide political-economic
planning and cooperation—if the mix of economic potential and social pressures
are to be reconciled. Governance seems
to be a major issue; and the richness of New York in knowledge-based skills
(which are capable of earning a relatively high return) applied to
"cheap" information services is suggested as a way to finance its
increasingly costly infrastructure and earnings requirements. It is hoped that with the new directions of
growth the quality of life in the metropolis will increase, rather than
decline, and that "upward convergence" for a broad segment of society
will again be possible. However the
study presents a challenging research agenda directed not only at sustainable
development but an improved quality of life (focusing on new areas of growth;
the need for health and hospital workers; and improved education)—that should
be part of the goal of the next stage of this project.
Mexico City: Here the
focus is on fiscal challenges—due to the expertise of the authors and research
team linkages to the Finance Secretariat in Mexico City's urban administration.
[4]
The Mexican metropolis has no counterpart in
either the U.S. or Canada, given its high concentration of national production
and population, although New York's Metropolitan Area has similar
characteristics. The study maintains
with statistical evidence that Mexico City generates more fiscal revenues than
it receives, although this position is disputed by other regions of the
country. The recent budget deadlock in the Mexican Congress is testimony to the
debate over this issue. The authors
argue that the metropolis is paying a "tax" (the excess between
revenue and expenditure)to favor the leveling of per capita outlays throughout
Mexico. Revenue-sharing between Mexico
City and the provinces is an old issue in Mexico, related to the city's ability
to deal with burgeoning population. While many have come from outlying regions to add to the swelling urban
population, Mexico City's outlays on urban infrastructure and social support,
low as they are, tended to further the magnet-like "pull" factors on
migration from rural areas—just as the recent recession, increases in charges
for heavily subsidized urban transport and services, and concerns about overcrowding
served to reduce and even reverse population flows to the Federal District
core.
There
is the likelihood that Mexico City has gone beyond the point of positive
externalities of agglomeration at least for most of its industries, and the net
effect of additional population growth (if one includes environmental and other
quality of life elements) is probably negative. Hence relocation of its population on a voluntary basis (by
creating similar and less-costly urban support systems and subsidized services
elsewhere) would probably increase productivity and welfare in the country as a
whole. This is not the result of any
careful calculus, but it arises from an assessment of the general conditions of
Mexico City today when compared with localities to which production is already
relocating. The reduced role of the
state in the economy has made it less-important to locate industry and trade in
the central city near the government agencies on whose support profitability
used to depend. Urban congestion,
pollution, and security problems are increasing the tendency of upwardly mobile
households to respond to incentives to relocate elsewhere. This has been an important motive for the
relocation of elites and middle-classes to places such as Tijuana. This is similar to New York City and its
surrounding metropolitan area—and dramatic improvements in communications
technology and services have also lowered the opportunity cost of moving to
places such as Connecticut—or to relocating "back office" systems as
far away as the mid-west or far west.
Zeroing
in on urban finance in this chapter opens the door to a number of more basic
structural problems which deserve further study in the next phase of
research. The budgetary approach taken
has the advantage of being able to develop more detailed examination of
interdependence-related issues as they affect fiscal policy but the
disadvantage of leaving out many other dimensions which could prove important
in assessment of the impact of changing patterns of integration. Changes elsewhere associated with
liberalization and globalization have reduced the scope for endogenous growth
policy of the metropole. Other regions
are gaining degrees of freedom for decision-making well beyond that of fiscal
federalism. The brief description of its
salient economic characteristics, as provided by the authors, helps one to make
a broader assessment of Mexico City's fortunes.
The paper focuses on two
periods, 1983-88 and 1989-94, beginning with the aftermath of the 1982 crisis
which found Mexico over-dependent on the public sector and on expected (but
unrealized) surpluses from oil discoveries that had propelled growth since the
late 1970s. The situation in the
early1980s underscored the need to restructure Mexico City's fiscal system just
at the time when it was needing more, rather than less, revenue to maintain any
semblance of support for a burgeoning population. The end of the second period marked a crisis(1994/95) which
highlighted the strengths and weaknesses of fiscal restructuring. This led to the city's first mayoral
election and to a political turnover in administration (1997) in which the PRD
assumed power in the Federal District, the PAN won many suburban posts, and
there was a resulting takeover (from the PRI) of all major elected posts by
opposition parties from the left and right.
Hence
the major decision—what degree of funding at the Federal level should be
apportioned to the Federal District (D.F.)--is now complicated by party
politics. The Party of the Democratic
Revolution (PRD) Mayor of Mexico City,Cuautemoc Cardenas, is expected to
challenge the successor to ErnestoZedillo who will be the PRI's candidate for
president in the year 2,000.Too much Federal support for the D.F. budget from
the PRI-controlled national government can strengthen the opposition; too
little can weaken the PRI's dominance which is already being challenged in many
parts of Mexico, partly because of problems addressed in this volume.
The tradeoff between major
urban development and that of outlying regions and smaller cities becomes
vital, not only for Mexico's overall growth and welfare, but for the country's
democratic evolution and long-term stability. This is not as sharply defined in New York, though the mayor and
governor, even when they represent the same party, have different
constituencies, class interests, and dispositions to favor social programs
(that are disproportionately large in NYC)—tugging in opposing directions for
the state's fiscal resources. But there
is also a federal dimension of revenue-sharing, in which national funds moved
to New York State do not necessarily benefit its majority—and because the New
York metropolitan area itself includes other states with their own
revenue-sharing problems. The tug of
war between the city and state for federal revenue-sharing in New York is quite
different from Mexico's Federal which has its own direct access to federal
funds—though it certainly affects those suburban areas of Metropolitan Mexico
City which extend into several surrounding states. Such conditions illustrate the problem of subregional
integration, in which contiguous economic zones do not have common political or
institutional mechanisms that can take a holistic view of urban growth problems
and the need for common approaches to fiscal policy and development incentives.
Demographic
growth, although slowing, remains high in Mexico City—which now holds about
one-sixth of the nation's population (compared to one-fourteenth for the NYC
Metropolitan Area.) As the birth rate
has fallen, the age structure is shifting toward those in working years. This makes economic growth crucial to the
city's future and increases the likelihood that it will become a source of,
rather than a destination for, new job-seekers. Hence employment openings in response to the burgeoning supply of
labor will be crucial for social welfare and stability in the core city of
Mexico and will determine the extent to which it will itself increasingly
become an entrepot for migration to other growing points—including the north
and west. During the 1980s Mexico City
had already begun to be an important source of migration to the U.S. and this
may be expected to increase. Along with
jobs, public transportation infrastructure and mid-income housing are listed as
the key areas for public sector support to complement private sector growth in
the Mexico City area. As in the case of New York, the need includes the
maintenance, shoring up, and replacement of depleting infrastructure—a very
large drain on the budget just to keep the city in the same condition as
before—plus new telecommunication networks and health care systems to serve its
aging population and new migrants.
For New York there is
accentuation of a dual class-structure, sustained by a new pattern of
immigrants from "developing regions" outside of the traditional
European sourcing areas, consisting of Latin Americans, South and East Asians,
and to a lesser extent Africans, as well as immigrants from the former
"Eastern Bloc.” Mexico’s urban migration remains largely domestic in
nature—though from more distant regions—and its poorer population is filling
outlying areas, causing a mushrooming demand for subsidized water, waste
disposal, transportation, housing, health, education, and other social
services.
This places a major strain
on the city's budget at the very time when existing resources are being
squeezed by fiscal cutbacks at the Federal level as well as high real interest
rates in response to tight monetary policy. As with NYC and Toronto industrial employment is down as a share of
total jobs in the city, while services, commerce, and transport dominate—with
one-fourth of the jobs in the public sector. Needless to say, as the government goes, so goes Mexico City's job market
as it presently is structured. Investment
is moving away from the core city, following the disincentives of rising costs
of D.F. location and falling benefits of being near the (weakened)government
agencies. Labor costs are lower
elsewhere, especially considering the taxes paid to sustain urban
infrastructure in an already-overgrown metropolis. Environmental concerns also encourage location of some industries
elsewhere. Moreover the power of unions
is less outside of Mexico City—and the cost of supplying urban demand for goods
and services from more distant locations is falling with the new transport and
communication technologies.
Opening
of the national economy, according to the authors, has "weakened the
traditional engines of development" for Mexico City—by eliminating a
captive internal market and widening the access of consumers to imports not
only from NAFTA partners but from the lowest-cost suppliers in the world
(including China, Korea, and South East Asia.) The astonishing growth of black market commerce since liberalization suggests
that contraband may also be increasing, as lower transaction costs make it more
profitable to circumvent the already-lowered legal barriers to exchange. So as demand soars, production atrophies in
the core city. And exchange rate policy
which affects the relative price of tradable versus non-tradable (the real
exchange rate as it devalues increases the tradable/no tradable price ratio and
favors import-competing goods and services, and vice versa) has not helped
during the periods of gradual revaluation of the peso/dollar exchange
rate—after sharp adjustments for devaluation in 1982 and 1984. Hence trade liberalization disincentives for
domestic manufacturing (by lowering protection barriers) have been augmented by
de facto revaluation of the peso (causing it to slide more slowly, against the
dollar, to "anchor" domestic prices which tend to rise faster than
those in the U.S. or Canada.) Capital
inflows in response to tight monetary policies have added to the peso
valuation—relieved only in the crisis periods—and forcing structural change in
Mexico away from the kind of "protected” production that helped to spur
Mexico's growth during the "miracle" years of import-substituting
industrialization.
All
of this may well be good for the economy, but it is hard on the central city
and its budget—which is simply a reflection of structural changes and the
related policy shift from protection to openness and from public sector command
economy to one in which the market is allowed to work more freely. Meanwhile, Mexico City has become a haven
for those caught in the process of structural change and in the shifting labor
market, and especially those younger cadres who have left the lagging rural
regions in search of a better life. This is a phenomenon that is observed in all so-called "emerging
market" economies, from China to Brazil, but it is particular important
for Mexico which needs to absorb labor in higher productivity jobs if it is to
realize its market potential.
The consequences for those
responsible for combining growth with the public interest (including education
and training in the forging of a new” social compact") are enormously
challenging. How do you bring about
structural change, by allowing incentive structures to render unproductive
important parts of the economy in order to spur others? How do you adjust to major international
shifts in the pattern of production, distribution, and, at the same time,
provide households with a sense of involvement, social well-being, and hope for
their children—avoiding the despond of underemployment, urban overcrowding,
deteriorating health and sanitary conditions, and criminal activities in one's
own neighborhood? What can be done when
this is accompanied by a sharpened view of luxury and privilege on the other
side of the freeway? One does not need
moral imperatives to recognize that middle-class self-interest (not to mention
that of a growing elite) demand the competitiveness and stability that comes
from shared development—especially when the mobility of capital is growing,
infrastructure is decaying, and the alternative is to move to safer havens
abroad.
The
chapter calls for greater participation of all citizens in the fiscal
process. This requires improved
city-federal cooperation, including the mushrooming barrios and affluent
suburbs that fall outside of the Federal District. Owing to recent political developments in Mexico City, the
challenge is even greater since the mayor is no longer a federal appointee and
the broader urban area has tended to polarize between the conservative PAN
party in the middle-class suburbs and the PRD in the barrios. In Washington D.C. there is a similar
problem, though the relatively much smaller Federal District of the U.S. faces
a much greater fiscal and social crisis than Mexico City, while the suburbs of
Washington enjoy expanding prosperity. This growing urban gap, and its resulting political challenge, is a
phenomenon occurring throughout North America that puts the situation of Mexico
City in perspective.
The U.S. Congress maintains
a strong voice in the fiscal conditions of Washington D.C., even as Mexico City
has now been given more leeway regarding its budget vis a vis the Federal
Government. But in Mexico the national
"fiscal coordinating pact" is
much more like a zero-sum game owing to the gigantic size of the capital city.
With the PRI no longer controlling Congress, there is an increasingly strident
call by the states for a larger share of the "pie," particularly in
the northern border states. The Mexico
City metropolitan area has within its territory middle and upper income
localities which had previously benefited from major subsidies in
infrastructure and public services, including energy, water, sewage disposal,
transport, and communications. Privatization and increased user fees have
already augmented the tax base. The location and easy identifiably of poverty
areas make targeting of subsidies possible. Hence there is the potential for urban fiscal policy to become more
distributionally-oriented in the future in terms of both taxes and
expenditures, provided that disparate constituencies are able to reconcile
their very different interests. But the
allocative effect of new taxes and fees, and their viability in a nation
attempting to democratize and decentralize, in the face of competitive
international pressures, has yet to be fully studied, according to this
excellent report.
Greater
Toronto Area: The Canadian
experience has many parallels with the other two major urban areas presented
above. However the authors have gone
somewhat further in actually engaging in econometric estimation of the impact
of trade on urban development in the Toronto area, vis a vis domestic market
swings and the structural changes that have been brought about by technological
innovation. Moreover there is a much
more detailed examination of the political evolution of suburban Toronto is
a vis the urban core in this study—which suggests the potential for such
analysis and its reconciliation with the process of competitiveness and
economic change. In the future it would
be useful to explore the fortunes of adjacent regions south of the Canada-U.S.
border, including adjacent urban areas in Michigan (such as Detroit), upstate
New York, and cities of the U.S.Midwest that were hard-hit by forces of the
shifting international market and the pattern of industrial change (especially
the auto and auto parts sectors, which have prospered in terms of NAFTA trade
and investment, but have created major problems for some U.S. cities and opened
up new opportunities for others.)
This chapter has three main
sections; the first two address the political challenge of reconciling the
interests of the Toronto core and its expanding surroundings; the third deals
with major forces bringing about economic change in the Greater Toronto Area
(GTA). The impact of trade, technology,
and demand on the region are subjected to rudimentary econometric tests for the
periods 1976-86 and 1990-92, two periods associated with a major trade cycle
and structural change—in which the growth of the GTA is examined under
different counterfactual hypotheses of "what might have happened" if
the economic structure had not changed vis a vis observed
performance. The results are used to
predict what might be expected to happen in the future.
One
of the major findings is that the structural change from opening up of the
regional economy through the Canada-U.S. Trade Agreement and NAFTA has-been
significant. A surprising and
encouraging result is that the greater Toronto economy, which used to be
associated with a considerable amount of import-substituting production of
goods and services, turns out to have benefited from the greater availability
of low-cost imports since trade liberalization. Increased access to outsourcing, while costing some jobs, has
permitted firms in the region to restructure along the lines of increased
global competitiveness leading to net gains overall. This is what had been hoped by ardent free-traders, but the study
seems to reveal that for Toronto it did in fact happen—though with considerable
dislocation and disproportionate population growth into the greater
metropolitan area and away from the central core.
Part of this pattern of
urban spread is due to an unbalanced tax structure in which property taxes are
much higher in the core than the periphery—financing infrastructure and
services which seem to have provided low-cost externalities to those living in
the lower-taxed suburbs. This appears
to be a universal phenomenon as noted above for both the New York metropolitan
area and greater Mexico City.) How
important is the "free-rider" problem of suburban development that
depends on the central city to support the economic base (e.g. high wage
employment of executives and staff who work in the city but live in the
suburbs) on which the metropolitan area depends? Is it sustainable or is it likely to lead to a collapse of the
inner core on which the suburbs depend? Is there a political solution to the expenditure-sharing problem and the
related tax-sharing requirements of urban/suburban symbiosis? These are issues which the study highlights
and which must be explored in greater detail in the future.
With
regard to its trade patterns, Ontario itself runs a trade surplus with the rest
of Canada that tends to offset its deficit with the rest of the world. The Greater Toronto Area (GTA) was much
harder hit than the rest of Canada in terms of jobs lost from the 1990-92
recession, but the resulting restructuring and recovery has-been faster and
more sustained than the country at large. This suggests that in some respects central cities may be in a better
position to shift their economic base (faster) than other regions—perhaps in
part because of their greater access to financial capital and a pool of
available labor with a wide range of skills that can readily adapt. This is the
other side of the coin for major metropolitan areas when faced with new
challenges; they may well have more flexibility and growth potential, but they
also have more traditional activities to cut back on, forcing them to deal with
a large population that is to some extent displaced by newcomers who are more
employable. (This is reflected in the
"stubbornly" high continuing unemployment in the Toronto region.)
The
regional trade analysis undertaken by the Toronto study, which deals with
inter-regional as well as international trade flows, best reflects the approach
proposed in the conceptual chapter of this volume (chapter one.) In future work
on the new regional approach to trade and development, one expects that a
specific locality’s comparative advantage will be reflected in the pattern of
production and employment, not only among countries but also within them. This will be affected by macroeconomic
policy. For example, during the period studied the downswing in fortunes of the
Toronto economy were related to anti-inflationary policy at the national
level. Attempts to fight inflation by
tight monetary policy raised the value of the Canadian dollar working against
export-led growth and encouraging imports. (More recently the Canadian dollar has fallen sharply, reversing the
impact on trade.) Canada's tight money policy and revalued dollar had an
adverse impact on localities such as Toronto which were vulnerable to the
competitiveness of the country's exports and the price of competing
imports. The consequences for the
Toronto economy are covered in the chapter. However the ultimate result was that restructuring plus regained fiscal
stability at the macro level ultimately permitted Toronto to eventually benefit
from trade-related growth, once the Canadian dollar had fallen to more
competitive levels.
The
affect of Toronto's restructuring in response to changing comparative advantage
and macroeconomic policy had a sectoral impact on employment that is outlined
in the chapter. As in New York, clerical positions were lost in both
manufacturing and services—driven in part by globalization but also by the
advent of new information technologies. (The very technologies which have fostered "globalization" by
reducing transaction costs seem to have hit urban employment, not as a result
of international competition per se but as a consequence of the new
productivity-enhancing and hence labor-displacing technologies. While this expands
the scope for new job-creation, to make use of displaced labor, the adjustment
takes time and may occur elsewhere than at the original location. Hence the regional consequence of
globalization is the internationalization of both production and
employment and regional dislocation—which could dampen the growth of central
cities but which may also increase the disposition of labor to migrate from
lagging regions toward the big cities which are believed to be "new
job" centers (the existing centers and their surrounding regions act as
magnets—even as they attempt to deal with their own misemployed.) The resulting labor market asymmetries may
lead to a decline in real wages and incomes of those workers must vulnerable to
dislocation from previous jobs, along with an increase in real wages and
incomes of those migrating to the urban centers from a lower base. The net effect appears statistically to be
"downward convergence" —but it represents a composite of two separate
components of labor supply, responding to changes in the structure of labor
demand.
The authors of the Toronto
chapter provide evocative results in their conclusions, indicating that during
the two periods the relative importance of globalization per se was below that
of technology or the business cycle downswing—and in the second period (1990-92
compared with 1976-86) the recession takes preeminence over technology. [However it may be said that technology
itself led to the conditions that forced restructuring and contributed to the
recession in the second period. The
eventual recovery of the Toronto area may be a bellwether for those
economies—like Mexico City—that must endure a trying period of restructuring
before emerging in a new wave of growth.] The study makes a sharp point that is worth emphasizing in
general—namely that domestic demand (the non-traded sector) is very important
as a contributor to the overall development process—and it can be badly hit by
the restructuring process.
The results of the Toronto
study show that it is essential for those interested in the growth of
metropolitan areas to pay attention to expansion paths that stimulate a balance
between domestic and foreign demand—and not be complacent solely with external
"engines of growth." Exports
alone will not be sufficient to sustain the demand for nontaxable on which
employment depends (and which contribute to the widening of income
distribution, rising real wages, and stability.) Upward convergence requires a two-pronged strategy in which
on-tradable activities prove to be far more than just a "multiplier.” They
are important in their own right. Otherwise "trade-led growth" by itself can lead to downward
convergence or even divergence between returns to labor and capital. The study also shows that business cycles
play a major role in regional development—challenging the new theories that
growth can take place in an uninterrupted path; instead it shows that even
growth induced by the new wave of technologies leads to structural changes that
have a major destabilizing impact that needs to be addressed by macroeconomic
policy (but the openness of economies makes such policy much more difficult
than simple closed economy macro-economic analysis would suggest.)
A Conceptual Note on the
Wage Convergence Effect of Globalization on Regions:
Not surprisingly the
literature is somewhat inconclusive and even controversial as to whether
globalization is leading to upward or downward convergence of productivity and
wages. From a political viewpoint the
matter is more importantly whether individual workers are experiencing
dislocation and a reduction in wages if they come from previously prosperous
regions, while others are experiencing rising wages if they come from
"lagging" regions. This is
the result of shifting tastes and technologies as well as the consequence of
trade and migration for the ability of labor in "high wage" jobs to
share in the scarcity rents ("above-normal profits") of goods and
service production which confront an increasingly competitive international market.
The fact that
"innovation rents" and other profits from special knowledge and
privately held technology have shorter half-lives, and that the increasing
competitiveness of labor markets prevents workers from extracting
"monopoly rents" from the threat of strikes and collective
withholding of labor services, is bound to have a negative effect on real wages
of those privileged to work in activities where there is a "rental
income" to capital which can be shared with labor. Hence the automobile and steel industries in
the U.S., when faced with declining scarcity rents in the 1960s and 1970s,
found it not only possible but necessary to cut wages (the wage share of those
rents)—but when they recovered their fortunes through restructuring, they were
able to retain a higher share of value added than before. They were able to cite global competition
and the threat of relocation and job-cuts in order to improve their
profitability and retain lower real wages, effectively weakening union
opposition.
While this is associated
with globalization it is not a direct consequence of international trade and
investment liberalization—though it is an effect of factor market opening
through the broadened process of exchange and changes in the de facto
bargaining (and power) positions of both domestic enterprise and labor unions, vis
a vis those firms able to take advantage of internationalization and
consolidation of production and investment. The net effect is to foster efficiency and productivity, increasing the
potential for international growth and prosperity. But a short-term consequence is to create market forces that
produce the appearance of "downward convergence" in wages without a
comparable reduction in profits. Hence
the global functional distribution of income in terms of wages versus profits,
interest, and rent, declines and income concentration takes place. This can feed back on the growth of demand
and global market potential—and can short-circuit the internationalization
process—unless efforts are made to increase the share of labor in value added
in productivity-enhancing way rather than through simple transfers. This includes importantly attention to the
supply and demand for "no tradable" goods and services in domestic
economies and to the provision of economic and social infrastructure (including
education and skill-formation) that provide positive external economies to the
production process and widen the pattern of distribution so as to permit the
diffusion of productivity growth.
For those activities which
are nontaxable, the end result may be lower value added (rather than physical
product) per worker resulting from a fall in relative prices as the supply of
those services rises with a weak employment situation (just as the relative
price of services rises in a tight labor market). The same trend can happen with tradable, if the supply of labor
is abundant (through, e.g., globalization of labor-intensive production and
outsourcing to low-wage per unit of physical productivity locales), leading to falling
relative prices in labor-intensive tradable (from electronic equipment to
garments) that lead to a reduction in the marginal value product of labor
(greater than the rise in marginal physical product of labor) and hence in real
wages and incomes of low-skilled workers employed in those industries. Whether the fall in relative prices of
tradable outstrips that of nontaxable depends on the international exposure of
the economy and its growth potential. Both are influenced by the openness of the nation to a new flow of
financial capital and investment—which affect (along with current account
behavior) the real exchange rate, with different impacts on each region.
Border Regions North and
South
Cascadia: This relatively prosperous region that links the
northwest of the U.S. and Canada is in the process of defining itself in terms
of size, scope of integration, and the institutions needed to bring about
sub-regional cooperation in the context of the broader FTA and NAFTA agreements
(and the Canadian Agreement on Internal Trade—CAIT.) Given the early stages of formulation of the "Cascadia"
region—the section is highly descriptive, optimistic, and enthusiastic rather
than analytical.
The
similarity of the NW region’s state and provincial components is noteworthy, in
terms of their traditional dependence on staples-based export-led growth with a
recent shift into higher technology manufacturing and services stimulated by
proximity to the Pacific Rim market. Physical contiguity of the NW has been influenced by the importance of
water-based rather than land-based transport until recent decades. Today highway links are binding the
localities into a "corridor" that promises to make one long
metropolis out of the three population centers, greater Vancouver,
Seattle-Tacoma, and Portland.
Finance
is flowing within the North West, propelling startups and furthering
growth. There does not yet appear to be
any significant amount of fiscal cooperation or collective effort at
infrastructure development among the sub-regions—a likely burden of the
international nature of Cascadia. Manufacturing (aircraft industry and electronic software) is
steady—while growth tends to be focused in commerce and services (including
ecotourism) which are important revenue-sources. In terms of social and demographic change, globalization has
stimulated a considerable influx of population to the region. Especially on the Canadian side of the
border in the Vancouver area, East and South Asian population have expanded
rapidly, bringing with them large amounts of financial capital for investment
in the region. Canada's migration laws
have required new settlers from non-traditional places of origin to bring with
them large amounts of investable funds per household in order to secure visas. In the major metropolitan areas of Cascadia
the study cites the significant growth of black populations, from a very low
historical base, responding to the relatively positive opportunities for
employment and income in the region. There is also a considerable amount of migrant labor from Mexico
settling in the rural areas and small towns in Washington State and
Oregon. This has played a key role in
the expansion of its in export-based horticulture.
Trade
from Cascadia is mainly outward—to the Pacific Rimand the rest of North
America, though the study reports a growing region-wide exchange (commerce)
linked to trade with the rest-of-the world trade and resource transfers within
the U.S. (e.g. mining, gas, and oil
from the NW producing regions to west coast cities.) In addition to merchandise trade, discussions sessions at the
1995 Vancouver meeting of this project stressed the importance of cross-border
traffic between the U.S. and Canada. The immense flow of vehicles between both parts of Cascadia has
benefited by the issue of binominal vehicle permits permitting those who drive
frequently across the border to circumvent slow customs procedures. This is said to bring about with enormous
savings in time, increasing the scope for region-wide exchange by lowering
transaction costs. "Full
exchange" seems well on its way toward happening in the Cascadia Region,
though population movements between the U.S. and Canada are simplified by the
already-existing convergence in productivity and incomes. The problems with similar patterns of
exchange between Mexico and the U.S. are exacerbated by the gap between the two
economies, especially in terms of wages and income.
Resource
rents which are high per unit of population give a potential for savings and investment
(including the expansion of social infrastructure)in the Pacific Northwest that
is already high for the two nations. The mobilization of mineral resource rents is already well-underway in
both Alaska and the NW Canadian provinces; through the establishment of
"resource trust funds," though the federal, state and provincial
institutions controlling their use are widely dissimilar.
The opening to liberalized
global trade and finance of transnational sub-regions such as Cascadia in the
northwest, and the southwest corridor between Ventura, California and Ensenada,
Mexico is having a transforming effect in terms of both production and
demographics. Population flows
themselves play a key role in expanding their dynamic comparative advantage, by
increasing the productivity of local resources and expanding the base of
consumer demand. While national
policies play a key role in setting the framework for sub-regional
decision-making, their problems are unique. They for innovative
institution-building and greater cooperation at the local, state, and
provincial levels and between countries. Promotion of sustainable development and social prosperity in such
regions cannot be left to national policy or broad multinational organizations
such as NAFTA. These objectives must
become the responsibility of the localities themselves—working together across
borders for the common good—however rudimentary and unprecedented such efforts
appear to be at the outset.
San Diego-Tijuana
Region: This is part of a larger regional
economy considered for the study(Ventura--Ensenada) which has been singled out
for more detailed analysis because of the amount of research already done on
these two border urban areas. The
southern (Mexican) part of the sub region has grown since the very beginning
from links with California and the U.S. economy because of (not
in spite of) the existence of a
national border dividing two different legal systems, institutions, and social
conditions between south and north. The
future of the corridor from Baja California to Southern California still
depends heavily on asymmetrical markets for goods and services (including
labor) and "internationalization" of the Southwestern economy (as
part of the Pacific Rim.)—an economy which gains in size and economic
potentials border barriers are lowered. But there are many reasons why barriers have remained—especially to
migration—and why the U.S./Mexico border policies differ from those between
Canada and the U.S.
Environmental
affects (pollution from "south" to "north") are discussed
in this chapter and are predicted to become increasingly important as
population and production swell along the border. Demographic changes insane Diego (and Tijuana) reflect the flow
of labor from southern to northern job markets; the profile of Sandi ego itself
has changed dramatically in recent years. There is a growing need for new "border institutions" that
focus not only on cross-border problem-solving, but that promotes joint
development projects, transport, and infrastructure that could benefit all
parties. Maquiladoras reveal some of
the potential for linked development in which labor stays south of the border
but the manufacturing process takes advantage of subregional comparative
advantage. Third countries (e.g. Japan
and Korea)have responded to the potential for such linkages—and the profits
they imply—especially given the concern that the open part of "open
regionalism" will be honored in the breach and that trade diversion may
well occur in the future (favoring Mexican suppliers over Asian outsourcing to
U.S. markets.) Under the rules of NAFTA
many Asian companies have established component production facilities in
Tijuana to take advantage of "penalties" for components produced
outside the North American region. The
choice of Tijuana as a site for such activities is due to lower labor costs,
adjacency to existing maquiladoras, and other locational advantages—including
the proximity of the western U.S. market and adjacency to the Pacific Rim.
The
initial findings suggest that there may have been some "divergence"
in recent years, with average living standards actually lowered on both sides
of the border but more in Mexico than the U.S. Part of this is related to the weakness of the Mexican economy in the
1980s (and falling real wages after 1982), partly to the recession of the early
1990s and peso crisis of 1995, and to push factors that have spurred job search
on the Mexican side of the border, lowering the opportunity cost of labor on
both sides. (No hard data is offered
for entry level wages in Tijuana or San Diego, either in nominal or real
terms.) The population of San Diego is
converging toward that of Mexico in terms of number of Hispanics (between
1980and 2000 the Hispanic share is projected to have risen from 15 to
25percent.) The English-language
competence of arrivals is limited. Educational levels differ sharply (though
they are higher for Tijuana than for Mexico at large.)
Federal
government military jobs in San Diego are still over 9%of total employment (cf.
1.7% for U.S.) While the economy was
hard-hit by cutbacks in military expenditures in recent years—this is being
partially offset by non-defense service activities such as tourism and new
manufacturing growth, though not enough to prevent the malaise in per capita
income in the San Diego area. In
Tijuana precipitate product actually declined from 1970-1990 as employment in
services and maquiladoras grew, drawing on the abundant supply follow-wage
labor from the rest of Mexico. Hence
growth in this larger transborder region has tended to be extensive rather than
intensive—with some evidence of divergence in productivity and incomes between
Mexico and the U.S. (this is different
from the trend reported in Arizona/Sonora where there seems to have been some
upward convergence in per capita output.)
San
Diego exports to Mexico account for 43 percent of its total foreign exports, a
share that exceeds that of any other large city in California(e.g. Los Angeles
or San Francisco.) Yet the perception
of Mexico as a potential market for California goods and services remains
under-appreciated. The state remains
focused on the Pacific Rim and has not yet recognized the importance of its
trade with Mexico, as compared with Texas which has been a strong promoter of
NAFTA, of roads and rail links among the three countries across the Rio Grande,
and of binominal commerce from the border southward.
What is being imported to
San Diego are primarily labor services in the form of migrant and commuter
workers who live in Tijuana. Commercial
links are important, with expenditures taking place in a "dollarized"
economy that crosses the border—hence the middle class and professionals in
Mexico feel swings in the peso/dollar exchange rate much more than their
compatriots elsewhere. And even
maquiladora investments respond importantly to the real value of the peso, so
that the crises of 1982 and 1994 stimulated cross-border manufacturing. But the exchange policies that originate
from the two national capitals and from global financial markets have a very
strong exogenous destabilizing effect on the border regions (as do Canada/U.S.
dollar fluctuations as we have seen.) Capital flows and immigrant remittances are very important to the
cross-border economy. Mexicans rely on
U.S. banks to avoid exchange risk, to ensure that their savings will not be
subject to political risk, and for tax purposes. Remittances to Mexico are vitally important to the domestic
economy, reflecting a return to the export of "labor services" which
benefit poorer households and localities.
The
general impression is that Tijuana-San Diego have yet to develop an effective
trans-boundary mechanism for cooperation in growth-enhancing approaches to
subregional development—or to ensure environmental harmony or attention to the
problems and potential for "managed interdependence" of labor
markets, innovation, and penetration of the global economy. Much remains to be done. Meanwhile the dead weight cost of problems
arising from proximity seem to have darkened the political horizon --including
drugs, urban crowding, and pollution. Hopefully the enormous potential that
could arise from a fuller integration of financial capital, resources, skills,
and know-how of the U.S. southwestern economy and northwestern Mexico may
become an engine of growth for the economies of both countries. The rise of a
new political force in the U.S., the "Hispanic caucus" in Congress
(which plays an impressive bipartisan role), and the increasing role of
Hispanics in local and state politics from Texas to California, make it likely
that such issues will be addressed in the future. Political democratization in Mexico is leading to an increased
role for local and provincial governments in decision-making and fiscal
responsibility for subregions including those along the border. De facto cross-border cooperation among
local governments has already become an important reality along the border from
Texas to California. It remains to build on these foundations as part of a new
U.S.-Mexico constellation of subregional alliances for growth, just as with
Cascadia, and other cross-border areas of the U.S. and Canada.
Arizona-Sonora: This study complements that of San Diego-Tijuana by taking
explicitly into consideration the impact of growing linkages between two
regions separated only by a border along a common frontier. The distinction between
"functional" and "formal" integration that the authors
apply is useful. It makes sense in
terms of the efficiency-goals of integration strategies for form to follow
function, consistent with political and social wants on both sides of the
border. Indeed the "silent
integration" which has taken place historically between the two states
reflects a high degree of functionality—given national boundaries and the
differences in cross-border markets for goods and services including labor.
One
of the key findings of the study is that the region's growth of population and
production in the past has had little to do with "integration" per
se, either formal or informal. For the
U.S. side climate and mineral resources have attracted population to a state
with desertous mountainous terrain for much of its extension. Even its agriculture depends largely on the
irrigation of arid lands. At one point
east-we stand north-south rail links made it an important entrepot for
transcontinental U.S. and binominal transportation. It is evident that the attractiveness of the climate in Arizona
(when one adds air-conditioning and irrigation) is bringing in waves of middle-class
migrants from elsewhere in the U.S. who are demanding services provided by
low-cost labor from Mexico and abroad.
Population migrated to
northwest Mexico in the past century to take advantage of newly irrigated land,
proximity to U.S. markets, and the provision of services of the region as an
entrepot between the two countries. Only recently has this led to the evolution of manufacturing-based
activities, especially in urban centers such as Hermosillo. This is similar to the growth of the Tijuana/Tijuana
region that has recently moved from services to manufacturing activities.
After World War II the two
subregional economies began to be "integrated" through the growth of
Sonoran agriculture which became an important adjunct to the irrigated high-yield
farming of the Southwest—in both cases supported by substantial public sector
investments in infrastructure and accessing of water resources which acted as
subsidies to commercial agriculture (including benefits to the ejidal farms in
the Yaqui Valley of Sonora). When
horticultural trade with Cuba was blocked by U.S. policy after the Cuban
revolution, the market shifted to Mexico, and again Sonora provided an entrepot
for winter fruits and vegetables from fertile regions of the Northwest to the
U.S. market. Today, as with similar
regions of the U.S. southwest,Sonora's irrigated agriculture, though still
highly productive, is beginning to strain scarce resources (such as ground
water, dams, and irrigation systems) and is threatened by salinization and the
accumulation of chemical byproducts from fertilizers and pesticides.
Sonora, facing its own
limits to irrigated agriculture, is forced to explore the potential for
investment in tourism and other service activities, environmentally conscious
fish-farming and the growth of selected high unit value crops, as well as new
areas of manufacturing tailored to the availability of Mexican labor, raw
materials and primary products, and accessibility to U.S. and foreign markets.
In recent years population growth along the Sonora/Arizona border has become
increasingly involved in cross-border activities, not only because of its role
as "entrepot" between the two countries, but also through the boom in
maquila production in San Luis, Agua Prieto, Nogales, and a food processing
plant in Hermosillo. This calls for
improvement in roads, railroads, air-transport, and port facilities.
In terms of "formal
integration" of the two economies of Arizona/Sonora, beyond the transport
link, there remains considerable scope for future development. While firms such as the Ford Motor Company
have set up highly efficient assembly operations in Hermosillo, much of the new
commerce and manufacturing in both states—while similar in characteristics to
that of the San Diego-Tijuana region—is sensitive to bilateral asymmetries in
the cost of labor, including those differences that reflect macroeconomic
policy and strength of the respective currencies. Cross border commerce flourishes owing to differences in real
purchasing power of the two currencies and real incomes in Mexico—both of which
are highly sensitive to the peso/dollar exchange rate. As with commerce between Canada and the U.S.
commerce, the exchange rate really matters to relative prices.
[5]
Concern is expressed about
the durability of regional dependence on maquila-type cross-border production,
to the extent that it relies on wage/productivity gaps between the two
countries. If integration leads to
upward convergence in wages and salaries, the reason for integration industries
may be lost as the wage gap narrows. "Footloose" industries which located south of the border for
its comparative advantage of "cheap labor" will be forced to move elsewhere, to the extent that they
are sensitive to wage costs, if they are unable to accomplish proportional
gains in productivity. Firms which earn
"rents"(excess profits) from labor service arbitrage will also seek
profits elsewhere in low-wage regions. To the extent that firms are taxed to cover the cost of infrastructure
for themselves and their workers, or to internalize the cost of
"externalities” provided by government subsidies, the attractiveness of
the region will be reduced proportionately.
Oaxaca: This is one of the most beautiful and fascinating but also one of
the poorest regions in Mexico. Ironically the study indicates that the fiscal decentralization process
that is well underway may have adverse implications for backward regions such
as Oaxaca, unless major new productivity enhancing support programs are
developed. Increased revenue-sharing tends to be associated with more stringent
overall budget support from the Federal Government. Public sector outlays are diverted to activities more
complementary to directly profitable private sector investments than to social
and economic expenditures designed to spread the pattern of development and
productivity growth. Yet such
expenditures are desperately needed if growth is to be sub-regionally diffused
and socially equitable.
The authors point out that
under present conditions outlays on regional infrastructure must be designed to
maximize narrowly defined benefit/cost ratios (benefits being reflected in
private profits rather than "social returns") if regions are to
compete among themselves for private investment. This is the direct consequence of increased fiscal stringency
and a growing share of private investment in total
infrastructure-building. This has
important implications for lagging regions such as Oaxaca. There is little attention to the political
instability of this part of Mexico, other than to point out that under the
outgoing PRI governor relations had improved enough to make him uniquely able
to last a whole term.
This section indicates the
need to address the problem of social and regional participation in the gains
from trade and integration more directly and in more detail. Clearly there are reasons why important
states such as Oaxaca lag behind the general development process and why some
activities have done better than others. It is evident that there is something missing in the governmental
framework for project evaluation, at least at the state level. Little is said about previous programs such
as "Solidarity"(PRONASOL) under the Salinas administration which
attempted to provide resources to lagging regions yet were frequently accused
of having political rather than economic goals. The more recent social expenditures programs under President
Zedillo call for independent assessment in terms of regional and local
conditions, in the perspective of changing domestic and international trade, to
indicate the extent to which they are able to play a role in the diffusion of
productivity, income, and development rather than simply continuing the
historical pattern of income and consumption transfers and subsidized social
services.
The extent to which it is
possible to reconcile economic growth objectives with those of "social
participation"--through policies designed to diffuse productivity and
generate employment—remains to be seen. Clearly the Oaxaca study points out the need for such efforts, given the
mandate of globalization. However it
should be mentioned that such measures have not been explicitly addressed in
any of the three countries of NAFTA, so it is not surprising that none of the
case studies in this volume presents a coherent program for the evolution of
comparative advantage with social diffusion. It may be useful to look at specific projects, such as the road
improvements between Oaxaca and Mexico City., which were undertaken by the
public sector even in times of fiscal stringency and budgetary conservatism,
and when most major highway developments were relegated to the private
sector. While this topic is not
addressed in the chapter, there is evidence of much greater success of state
covering of transportation-related externalities in attracting truck traffic to
newly improved roads. This contrasts with the generally acknowledged failure of
privatized toll roads developed elsewhere. In fact, truckers throughout Mexico proved unwilling or unable to
compensate directly for the externalities involved in private road construction
by paying very high toll rates imposed for the use of the new privatized
freeways. However in the case of the Oaxaca-Mexico City freeway, highway
improvements(which did not charge commensurate tolls) have given rise to an
explosion of transport and related commercial activities benefiting the
regional economy. It would also be
useful to look in depth at education and other measures as they have related to
the development of this lagging region and to suggest what might be the
appropriate level and structure of revenue sharing, given the particular
characteristics of low income regions such as Oaxaca.
Newfoundland: This section deals with the consequences for poorer
regions of the impact of globalization on financial markets and the resulting
fiscal constraints which are imposed on Federal governments—which previously
provided transfers to lagging regions in order to reduce the income gap among
states and provinces. The problem is
that attempts to force upward convergence in an unequal economy through income
transfers, making use of the fiscal mechanism, tends to deal with effects
rather than causes of inequality. What
is needed for upward convergence of incomes is upward convergence of
productivity plus tightening labor markets(that permit real wages to move up
with productivity gains (by causing average gains in labor productivity to be
matched with marginal gains so that real wages can rise without resort to
inflation, transfers, or other subsidies.)
Newfoundland is a region
with a major industry, fisheries, that appears to have been worked beyond its
capacity—even as population and the labor force have grown. The chapter shows how attempts to deal with
rising unemployment levels created adverse incentives by relying on
unemployment insurance schemes (UI)supported by fiscal transfers from more
prosperous regions. The goal was income
maintenance rather than productivity enhancement. The insurance program provided the wrong kind of incentives,
leading to schemes (such as” lotto 10-42") which spread the minimal work
available plus the transfer payments to the maximum number of individuals. The result was to shrink long-term employment,
making everyone dependent on the dole, and stimulating activities that created
short-term jobs (including fisheries) regardless of the need for long-term
growth in regional productivity and employment. By providing income comparable to other regions for a minimum of
work effort, the scheme reduced the pressure on labor in Newfoundland to
migrate to more productive regions (from which they might have been able to
send remittances.)
As
with Oaxaca, the fiscal impact of "integration" turns out to have
greater consequences for this lagging region than trade liberalization per
se. In one case it reduces the scope
for social expenditures and infrastructure support. In the other it cuts into Federal relief for provincial
unemployment—forcing the region back on its own limited resources. Newfoundland dissimilar to Oaxaca, despite
the great differences between them in per captaincies, since in both cases
revenue-sharing turns out to be a mixed blessing. It brings with it "expenditure-sharing" that forces
backward regions to carry an even larger burden of their own social programs
than increased revenue transfers can support.
Even
the modest degree of revenue-sharing for the development of backward regions,
once an alleged goal of national governments, is now threatened in Mexico as in
Canada and the U.S. The market-enforced
discipline of fiscal stability, which derives from internationalization of
financial flows even more than from trade liberalization, has cut into the
usual schemes of regional transfers and subsidies for consumption and social
services. The danger is that this can
augment the disparities that already exist between regions and social
groups. There is also a danger that the
lack of such transfers in the North American context can exacerbate the
widening of productivity and income between Canada/U.S. and Mexico as well as
among the several subregions of NAFTA (in which a so-called "poverty
area" of the U.S. or Canada has the potential to be comparable in per
capital income to one of the more advanced regions of Mexico.)
In
the lessons learned from the Newfoundland experience, the author lists the
dangers of reliance on programs such as unemployment insurance (and, we might
add, simple income transfer mechanisms that are unrelated to
productivity-enhancement of the recipients and their regions.) Simple transfer programs tend to lock-in
dependency of labor on subsidies; work against reallocation of resources from
declining to expanding sectors (and regions); divert entrepreneurial activity into”
working the margins" of benefit schemes rather than seeking productive
investment; deal with symptoms rather than causes of poverty and
underemployment; fail to consider the behavioral response of beneficiaries to
wasteful incentives; make regional economies dependent on external support; developing
the underground economy in such regions; fostering intergenerational
dependency; failing to ensure upward convergence because they do not deal with
the underlying need for productivity gains. Increased economic integration and trade liberalization will make
transfer programs increasingly difficult to sustain.
To reduce income disparities
it will become more and more necessary to attack lagging productivity directly
and to raise wages by tightening the demand for labor throughout the
economy. Regions such as Newfoundland
and Oaxaca must identify projects that are profitable in their own right, even
though the return is based on indirect demand via the public sector. It is
necessary to explore the potential for expanding the growth of no tradable as
well as tradable goods and services—including construction, roads and other
infrastructure, education, health, parks and recreational activities, the arts,
and other social services to raise the quality of life for all regions and
income groups.
For backward regions the
type of transfers that will be self-canceling are growth-enhancing measures
from both the government and private capital markets—in response to new
investment opportunities that draw on a growing supply of productive labor and
a widening of local markets. Taking
advantage of such opportunities, once they have been identified, calls for
higher rates of regional savings and investment including openness to
investment from other parts of the country and abroad—including the creation of
financial intermediaries to attract such funds and venture capital for
risk-taking. It will also be important for such economies to support innovation
in” labor-using" technologies which raise output per worker while at the same
time attracting more labor in order to expand production. Global economic integration will facilitate
such expansion paths, along with the widening of markets in a virtuous cycle of
incentives that will draw backward regions into the productive process.
These
two chapters take a look at "backward" regions in Canada and Mexico’s
their host economies undergo major growth with structural change. They indicate that the impact of initial
asymmetries tends to widen rather than narrow the gap between regions at the
national level (not to mention the gap between the poorest regions of the NAFTA
partners.) It is necessary in future
studies to research similar lagging regions of the U.S. (such as West Virginia,
Arkansas, or Mississippi) for purposes of comparison and contrast. In addition it is useful to look at the
success of "growth poles" in greater detail. The section in this volume on Silicon Valley
indicates that even the most prosperous areas, which have already demonstrated
their productive potential, call for combinations of public/private sector cooperation
and decision-making needed to provide those services for which short-term
private profit-making may be inadequate.
Silicon Valley: This chapter provides a summary statement of the importance of
cooperation between local government, business, and interested citizens(e.g.
those in the educational community) to sustain development of region that has
already "taken off." In the
case of this high tech region of Northern California, initial prosperity of a
basically Schumpeterian type, in which innovative technologies were harnessed
by entrepreneurs with access to venture capital, to serve a rapidly expanding
domestic and international market, a downturn in the fortunes of the Valley in
the late1980s suddenly awakened a realization. The agglomeration effects of new technological creativity,
entrepreneurship, and flexible financing were not enough to avoid
recession. The reversal of the fortunes
of Silicon Valley at the end of the 1980s, as it seemed to be outgunned by
"high tech" production elsewhere (and the plummeting prices of high
tech products that were experiencing "commoditization"—like the cost
of information units or bites), forced a reassessment of the old libertarianism
and are thinking of the role of cooperation in the provision of public goods and
attention to positive externalities.
It was believed by the
practitioners of Joint Venture Silicon Valley (and activities such as
"Smart Valley") that government was not well-equipped to understand
the needs of the local economy or to provide on its own the appropriate
expenditure policies. On the other hand, private investors were constrained by
the requirement of short-term profit maximization (in a time of high and rising
real interest rates from globalization of financial markets and significant risk
discounts) from spending large amounts for "public goods" on an
individual basis. What was developed,
instead, was an innovative institution which merged public and private sector
interests and capabilities, supported by the educational community, going
beyond the patterns already established by Stanford University for incipient
private investors who leased space on its own land over the past several
decades.
While this chapter does not
go into the details of such institutions or processes, or the underlying
concepts associated with entrepreneurship,” innovation rent-seeking,"
agglomeration economies, and externalities associated with regions attempting
to pursue a comparative advantage in high technology—it opens a window into a
process of cooperation that is proving to be fundamental to sustained growth
even in one of the most legendary and privileged segments of the world’s high
tech economy. The chapter is written by
practitioners who have had experience with the process itself. The approach that has engendered "Smart
Valley" and other cooperative measures patterned after it recognizes that
those externalities associated with good government, information networking, educational
support (via public-private sector cooperation), and diffusion of profits from
innovation for broader-based infrastructure and human-capital formation, really
matter if even the most advanced regional economies are to succeed in the long
run.
It will be necessary in future
research and policy analysis to go beyond this chapter to determine the ways
and means to accomplish what is championed by this section of the study—and how
they might be applied to very different regions with similar objectives. But that is understandable, given the
limitations of the present volume and the complexity and novelty of the cases
surveyed and the approaches suggested. It is important in subsequent stages of research to mine information
from case studies of specific cooperative programs, such as Joint Venture
Silicon Valley (and those in other areas, including Chihuahua, Mexico, where
similar approaches have been taken), to better-understand the means of
achieving positive agglomeration economies and the growth with social stability
which this could permit. The question
remains, how many "smart valleys" can be accommodated in the new
global development process—the answer may be an infinite number, given the
potential in world demand, if society in general and not just a privileged few
living in the "valleys” are able to share in the process of innovation and
growth. For this to happen, this and
the other chapters in this volume indicate how important it is touring about
new forms of institutionalization and public-private sector cooperation, with
support from the educational community, in every region which hopes to attract
the new growth processes to their locales—or which wishes to remain in the
vanguard into the next century.
Arbitrage in tradable such as gasoline and groceries put
pressure on both governments to consider the implications of a de facto "currency
area" in which the answer to date seems to be "dollarization" on
the Mexican side of the border.
|