Mexico and the World
Vol. 2, No 4 (Fall 1997)
http://www.profmex.org/mexicoandtheworld/volume2/4fall97/chap1.html
Integrating Cities
and Regions: North America Faces Globalization
Edited by James W. Wilkie and Clint E. Smith
Associate Editor: Francisco Gil-White
Chapter 1
The Political Economy of Open Regionalism
Clark W. Reynolds
Stanford University
Introduction
What combination of market forces and public policies cause existing
economic and social gaps to widen or narrow during the integration process?
The regions of North America exhibit widely different levels of income,
productivity, and social access. Our goal is to explore the positive and
negative consequences of increased trade and investment liberalization,
migratory pressures, and the diffusion of new technologies and infrastructure,
as they are altering the economic and social la ndscape of Canada, Mexico,
and the United States. We term this the problem of asymmetrical integration.
This chapter will provide a framework to compare and contrast integration
experiences of subregions at different levels of development from a political
economic perspective. The approach is intended initially for cases in North
America and the Caribbean Basin. It is used to show how within each subregional
entity as well as between its neighbors different patterns of integration
affect g rowth, distribution, and political change, especially through
increasing or decreasing economic and social imbalances that already exist.
A conceptual model is applied in which each locality chosen is regarded
as an "open developing economy" engaged in trade with adjacent
areas, the rest of the nation, its integration partners (as in the case
of NAFTA), and the rest of the world. It is possible to study a region
in terms of its integration with the rest of the national economy, even
when it is not directly located in a border area, recognizing that regional
and global integration go well beyond border relationships. Howev er it
is also recognized that regions located on both sides of national boundaries
have particular characteristics that both facilitate and complicate the
national integration process. Issues explored are the gains (and possible
losses) from trade and gr owth (broken down by politically-relevant socio-economic
group), the effect of growth on distribution, the use of the political
process and institutional reform to affect economic policies, and the likely
repercussions of resulting policy changes on subse quent patterns of economic
growth and distribution. We hope to offer plausible new approaches to domestic
policy and regional cooperation that will reinforce the benefits of integration
and reduce the costs, so that market forces reinforced by wise publi c
policies will lead to upward convergence in productivity and income, benefiting
all participants through an equitable distribution of the benefits and
costs of adjustment. This policy approach is called "open regionalism"
with "social ac cess."
Political-Economic Characteristics:
The Prime Mover--Technology--Leading to Structural Change for Competitiveness:
In recent decades a new technological revolution has dramatically altered
conditions in the market place, forcing a readjustment of much of the industrial
structure of North America, opening up new areas of growth and closing
old ones. Increased t rade and financial mobility are accompanying and
accelerating this process. The changes are driven by investors pursuing
higher profits; workers seeking more reliable employment; and governments
responding to the growing demands of their constituencies f or "entitlements"
over against the greater need for fiscal responsibility in an internationalizing
capital market. This is evident by looking at the evolving pattern of production
and infrastructure in each of the three North American countries over the
past few decades. It is a main point of this volume that national overviews
are not enough. They show averages rather than specific impacts that work
themselves out in terms of social and political responses in decentralized
systems. Individu al subregional cases reveal what lies beneath general
trends, as specific sectors, regions, and social groups have their own
asymmetries.
The path of change can be demonstrated by using benchmark figures on
value added by economic sector (Gross Domestic Product and Gross Regional
Product), employment by sector, and factor income at the national, regional,
and local level. Value adde d figures show the level of production growth
and the pattern of change in output and employment among economic sectors.
Value added per employed worker reveals the proximate pattern of productivity
growth over the same period. The distribution of value added into profits/interest/rent
and wages/salaries reveals the functional distribution of income accompanying
growth with structural change. Relative price figures permit one to determine
how much the observed changes in income may be due to changes in the terms
of trade and how much to physical output and productivity growth. The most
difficult information to obtain concerns the functional distribution of
income (breakdown of value added by sector into returns to capital, land,
and labor). However t hese are the minimal levels of information needed
to reveal the relative pattern of production, productivity, and income
distribution of the subregions studied. For each subregional case it is
useful to identify and characterize the performance of at lea st the key
industrial activities (including agriculture, commerce, construction, education,
and public services) covering both leading and lagging sectors. Output
and employment figures will permit a disaggregation of the process of growth
with structura l change and price and income data will give some evidence
of the incidence of costs and benefits. Tradables and nontradables should
be included, recognizing that in many cases nontradable services represent
a large and growing share of employment, incom e, and expenditure. (Most
of the new jobs created in recent decades have been in so-called "nontradables"
including service occupations. Most of the jobs lost to structural change
are in "tradables" and especially in manufacturing oc cupations.)
The productivity growth figures identify those activities in which rising
value added per worker take place contributing positively to the production
space (and income space) that would permit a rising standard of living
to be enjoyed by the popu lation as a whole. The figures also reveal sectors
of stagnant and even falling value added per worker, where growth is either
extensive (no rise in the value of output per worker, as holds in many
assembly plants and maquiladoras) or declining. It is important
to relate the productivity and output performance figures to both exogenous
and endogenous influences. Changing patterns of international competition,
imported technology, and the impact of shifts in the terms of trade in
the world market are all exogenous factors. Endogenous growth elements
have to do with those linkages and induced shifts in product and process
technology, learning by doing, and economies of scale that are particularly
relevant to emerging markets of developing regions , where growth with
structural change involves important positive feedbacks.
Also endogenous is the provision of infrastructure that links local
markets to broader regional patterns of exchange and global integration.
For gains from trade to induce growth, there must be a continual adjustment
to shifts in the economy’s dyn amic comparative advantage. This calls for
local and regional cooperation to reduce transaction costs and increase
the responsiveness of decision-makers to changing conditions, including
the diffusion of productivity growth and social access (both elemen ts
of "open regionalism" strategies). In some cases it is possible
to take advantage of specific micro-studies at the local or sectoral level
that shed light on key indicators of productivity growth (or decline),
especially in terms of the appl ication of new technologies and patterns
of production. For example a closer look at the impact of economic integration
in North America on the trinational growth of two-way trade in autos and
auto parts, and the effect of plant location and outsourcing on wages and
salaries, and profits in the automobile industry can be very revealing.
The growing interdependence in autos and auto parts production among
the three countries of North America is partly a response to the increased
competitiveness from suppliers in Asia and elsewhere. It is necessary to
place subregional and North Am erican behavior in a global framework in
order to select out the role of regional and global integration in bringing
about changes in output, employment, and income at the local level. To
do so will require information about the impact on the local econo my of
the patterns of global trade and investment and, where relevant, on migration.
Since integration includes increasing exchange between the subregional
locality (and its individual industries and workers) and the rest of the
nation and region (as in NAFTA), it is useful to have some estimate of
the patterns.
[stopped here]
Market opening can lead to uneven growth paths both within and between
regions. Some "emerging regions" are growing faster than their
high-income advanced industrial counterparts. Some social and gender groups
are experiencing more impr ovement in productivity and income than others.
Losing regions, sectors, and social groups might even be experiencing "immiserizing
growth" (if the demand for their goods and services is sufficiently
inelastic so that relative prices are driven down more than output grows,
leading to a decline in their value added and income). This can be a mere
consequence of competitive market forces at work, rather than any application
of asymmetrical market power or political conspiracy of the strong again
st the weak. Growth that widens inequality can lead to new "transaction
costs" (e.g. insecurity of life and property, market failure, rising
defense costs--including "protection" blackmail). Here efforts
to share benefits and spread costs at the outset, through the formation
of new social pacts, might reduce the subsequent costs of market breakdown.
The absence of security at various points in an integrating world system
can lead to the relocation of productive opportunities and the proliferation
of crime.
Finance and Investment Impact and Macro-Economic Shocks: The
completion of markets during the process of economic liberalization and
opening (which is part of the "open" aspect of "open regionalism")
leads to a wholesale adjustment of financial institutions and financial
flows, moving from households, sectors and regions in which accumulation
exceeds physical investment to those which borrow in order to consume and
invest. The financial intermediation process and the gr owth of banks and
non-bank financial institutions has been celebrated for its role in facilitating
growth and development (by Goldsmith, Shaw, and McKinnon in his earlier
work) and for its susceptibility to market failure but clearly the integration
proce ss tends to begin with trade and finance. Unfortunately it can also
be a heavily destabilizing process, as we have seen twice in the past decade
and a half for Mexico and Latin America, and in numerous cases in the history
of debt default abroad and busi ness cycles at home.
We are attempting in this study to see how a subregional financial structure
evolves and articulates with the rest of the host country, its neighbors,
and the international system, and how that can be associated with vulnerability
of activities whi ch are sensitive to the sharp movement of real interest
rates and exchange rates--as in the case of Canada (rise and fall of Canadian
dollar), Mexico (fall, rise, and fall of the peso) and the U.S. (rise and
fall of the dollar vis a vis other hard currenc ies). All of this plays
havoc on real and financial decision-making, and especially on the process
of medium and long-term accumulation and investment which are central
to the readjustment of the productive structure of the economies being
considered, not to mention those whose livelihoods depend on such economies.
In addition, inflation and the price level, as well as the change in relative
prices (e.g. tradables and nontradables) resulting from increased exchange,
are important elements to consider in the studies.
The investment decision-making process is more than the interregional
and international movement of physical and financial capital; it has to
do with the spatial locus of decision-making and the scope of economic
processes and is as much psycholo gical as financial process (dealing
with, as Keynes termed it, "animal spirits"; it involves expectations
about subregional behavior, interacting with new technological opportunities
and challenges of competitiveness, subject to the kind of unce rtainties
which are part of the process of trying to cement new regional structures
and social groups, many of which speak different languages and have different
and often conflictive histories. How the process is addressed case by case,
and subregion by subregion, will depend on the group involved but the
subject is central to our concern about development. The investment decision
must consider the relationships among labor, capital, technology, exports
and imports, and how they influence domestic an d international institutions
both public and private.
It is increasingly important to examine the implications of growing
interdependence for the subregional economy’s vulnerability to macroeconomic
shocks. Changes in trade policy, sharp changes in macroeconomic behavior
through business cycles, vari ations in monetary policy and interest rates,
inflationary behavior and the real exchange rate (often influenced by monetary
policy which may in turn be influenced by shortcomings in fiscal policy)
all have major importance for activities dependent on &qu ot;open regionalism"
across national borders or in separate policy domains (e.g. local fiscal,
environmental, social, and even non-tariff policies affecting major tradables,
as well as the treatment of investments and finance among regions). Such
is sues have assumed much greater relevance since the recent recessions
in the three North American economies, the peso meltdown, and swings in
regional trade, finance, and balance of payments.
Labor Market Impact: The level and pattern of employment have
changed accordingly. As a result there seems to be a growing polarization
of the work force, with immigrants being attracted to high wage regions
and to more productive educatio n and skill-formation so as to receive
a premium over unskilled wages. It is quite possible that in many cases
there will be an initial polarization of income levels and social structures
resulting from the challenge of competitiveness. The polarization may be
along racial lines, or by age and gender group. For this reason, we encourage
attempts to provide data on the structure of employment by industrial sector,
by occupational skills, and for wage (and nonwage) benefits, including
by social group if possible, as they have evolved over time, or at least
for benchmark periods, in the subregions studied. In some important cases
migration into or out of the region or sector is a key element in the process
of restructuring, as the changing supply of labo r responds to changing
patterns of demand. The new technologies have often facilitated the mobility
of labor perhaps more than they have lowered the cost of interception of
undocumented migrants. Responses of labor organization to the new challenges
of open regionalism are part of this process and should be considered to
the extent possible especially where this is relevant to the case involved.
Trade Impact: One clear manifestation of the new order has to
do with changing availability of imports and new markets for exports, and
ways in which this has been altered by trade policies (such as GATT, NAFTA,
the CBI, and bilateral agree ments). These changes present challenges and
opportunities for the existing structure of production and employment,
and for regional configurations that can be adapted to take advantage of
them. Clearly there are costs as well as benefits inevitable a s they
may seem to those who see a "silent integration" occurring as
the market conditions change. The opportunity cost of not responding to
the opportunities for profits (and for higher wages for those who respond)
becomes too high to prevent some from taking advantage, bringing about
adjustments often before society approves, or before the political forces
either recognize them or respond.
Social and Institutional Role: For those who benefited from the
old order, there are losses from change that cause a lethargic response
or even open opposition because they earn "scarcity rents" (directly
unproductive rent-seeking ) from the status quo. Newly emerging groups,
recent immigrants, some of the more energetic minority members, and entrepreneurs
in general tend to welcome the opportunities for more productive activities
that can earn abnormal returns to the innovators ( innovation rent-seeking)
and their employees. Even though such returns may well fall back as competitiveness
grows, lowering prices as well as costs toward more normal competitive
levels, there is a boomer mentality on the part of some that counteracts
t hat reaction of others who wish to "keep things as they were"
even though this may lead to costly obstacles to trade and investment,
migration, and technology transfer. In the subregions studied, we encourage
attempts to estimate such costs and benefits, which affect clearly identifiable
groups; often some workers will win while others lose, as will some investors
(e.g. more traditional one) and "go by the book" managers vis
a vis others who are more entrepreneurial. Unfortunately, f or specific
regions, there is no guarantee that for a given time period the balance
will be positive; some may see more industries move out than in more
lowering of wages and employment than raising while others will see a
general upward thrust. Thi s is the political challenge that can be understood
more clearly as the analysis spells out how the process is taking place
and what some of the recent historical counterfactuals and alternative
future trends might be as policies change.
Political Impact: The political process all too often lags far
behind the market process and the forces leading to "silent regionalism,"
but it is central to the legitimization of the new flows. It plays a key
role in building a bridge between interest groups. However, political structures
tend to be defined by historical patterns of exchange and problems of social
interaction and often have little to do with new challenges and opportunities.
In such cases the private sector in terest groups played a leadership role
in informing politicians of the new benefits from exchange (and often tended
to minimize or even ignore the costs.) This was clearly evident in the
case of U.S.-Mexican interdependence, in which labor markets, trade , investment,
technological change, and demand patterns become highly interactive long
before the political processes woke up to the phenomenon and began to recognize
benefits as well as costs (there is still a tendency for many politicians,
and especiall y those from disaffected regions, to focus on costs especially
in terms of labor/migration problem and the environment often for good
reasons from the viewpoint of opponents and their particular interests).
The political process can be shaped by NGOs and by the private sector
(as was the case with the binational U.S.-Mexico business groups), or by
the vision of the changing international system, the relentless integration
of which, alongside the forma tion of new regional blocs, forced the North
American central governments to see opportunities that had always been
more evident to those with a more transnational vision beyond their respective
borders. This helped to build support for the Canada-U.S. F ree Trade Agreement
and binational business groups lobbied their governments for unilateral
liberalization of U.S.-Mexico trade and investment that was the harbinger
of NAFTA. Each of the subregional studies will paint, in a brief summary,
a picture of t he ways in which the respective political institutions altered
in response to the realities and potential for gains from greater subregional,
region-wide (North American) and international interdependence.
It may well be useful in our studies to look at how the traditional
political party structure has had to evolve to deal with the recent challenges
of openness, regional integration, and competitiveness. It is a long time
since the parties in North America dealt with free trade versus high tariffs
as a central issue; openness worked for a nation that had a virtual monopoly
on many of the leading technologies in important sectors, as well as an
enormous and regionally integrated domestic market. The NAFTA debate
and subsequent GATT and "fast track" issues have brought the
issue to light but have also placed the sequencing of costs (which tend
to precede benefits for many voters) squarely in front of candidates anxious
to be re-elected . In addition, the attractiveness of subregional cooperation,
particularly across borders (e.g. in the case of San Diego/Tijuana issues
such as sewage disposal, a regional airport, treatment of the migration
question, and other pressing practical matters ), tends to be more evident
to local authorities than to those at the state or national level, and
requires considerable voter education even at the local level. The politics
of interdependence and international institution-building are being addressed
i maginatively (especially in the European context, but also for emerging
regions in the Americas and Asia) and form a rich and growing literature.
It is necessary to draw upon insights from such analyses, as well as from
practical experiences being studie d in this project. Hence it is useful
to spend some time in each study on the new politics of integration and
particularly in innovative ways that are being developed to bridge the
gap between satisfaction of local political responsibility (which becom
es more important with democratization and decentralization of decision-making)
and achieving the benefits of subregional cooperation and international
exchange.
Management of Interdependence: The practical problem of reconciling
winners and losers in the process of opening is a subject for both civil
society and political institutions. It operates at the firm level in terms
of new patterns of owne rship, management, worker participation from the
shop floor to equity ownership (through pension funds and stock options)
and in some cases to a more active role in innovation and management including
even positions on the board of directors. "Open regionalism"
is an analytical approach rather than a prescriptive slogan, dealing with
the way in which institutions, societies, and regions respond to the challenge
of international competitiveness so as to increase productivity and competitiveness
through the diffusion of best-practice technology, while ensuring that
there is an equitable social participation in the process beneficial to
the particular region in which the activities take place. "Regionalism"
reflects the need for coopera tion beyond specific local entities in order
to take advantage of proximity of neighboring institutions and individuals,
talent, capital, infrastructure, and markets, so as to realize greater
competitiveness in the "open" international market in which the
forces of change have inserted the local entities. The assumption is made
that no locale is an island anymore. All are impelled, by the human search
for a better life, and by those technologies which relentlessly facilitate
exchange and lower transaction costs, to experience "silent integration."
Hence the old orders will inevitably crumble. But many of them have values,
attitudes, and social harmonies which have been painstakingly institutionalized
over the centuries. Sometimes these took place at the cost of civil wars
or revolutions (as in the U.S. and Mexico) and sometimes through a difficult
process of federation of very different subregions (as in all three countries,
including Canada).
The "management" of "open regionalism" is a slow
and difficult process. NAFTA is a case in point. It leads to new coalitions,
as in the case of Cascadia and the Southwestern corridor from Los Angeles
to Ensenada; to the first efforts at cooperation between Arizona and Sonora;
to efforts in Texas and Northeastern Mexico which are not (yet) part of
our project. But also the management applies to major metropolitan areas
like greater New York and Metropolitan Mexico City, and to outlying regions
like Oaxaca, Chiapas, Newfoundland, and Arkansas which see a growing share
of their activities, both economic and social (and political) governed
by the mandate of international market forces and competitiveness, yet
no less needing to p rovide social bridges to the future and safety nets
for those less privileged and more wedded to traditions and structures
that are challenged by the new international system. In our case studies
there will be an effort to develop some of the more salien t pressures
and responses to such management of interdependence, brought about by the
forces of open regionalism, and to shed light on their social, political,
and economic implications. The attempt to promote a subregion’s competitiveness
or to retain t he edge that a region initially gained through a complex
set of forces that fortuitously gave it technological leadership such
as Silicon Valley is a central part of our project. While each case is
different, it is nevertheless essential to shed ligh t on those factors
which can augment competitiveness and quality of life, recognizing that
growth and development are often endogenous and responsive to unique private
and public sector initiatives. The same questions will be considered for
each of the s ubregions studied: What are appropriate management approaches
for competitiveness and positive social impact? How can they be consistent
with a satisfactory response to the negative pressures that are the heritage
of some regions more than others, and wh ich may be placing a major economic
and fiscal drain on their ability to restructure and grow?
The Open Economic Regional Development "Model": It
is evident that there is an implicit heuristic model underlying this approach
it is one of growth and development an essentially socio-economic model
of accumulation with inno vation and the advent of new opportunities that
respond to positive entrepreneurial behavior. The endogenous aspects of
growth are particularly relevant here including those social and institutional
conditions that facilitate an increase in what econom ic historian Walt
Rostow once called yields and propensities. These two elements
take away from the more mechanistic elements of so-called "growth
theory" which in the past stressed increases in savings and investment,
accumulatio n, and a rise in the ratio of both physical and human capital
to labor. Certainly some of the data asked-for in the case studies facilitates
the mechanistic approach. In addition there is the "open economy macro"
approach in which regions and activities which offer a greater return to
scarce resources (and especially mobile resources like financial capital
and entrepreneurship) will tend to attract both financial capital and labor
across borders or among regions (through migration and the spre ad of financial
intermediation) in order to earn abnormal profits (at least until new levels
of competition are achieved so that prices begin to approach marginal cost).
There is the "endogenous growth" dimension in which a stress
is placed on those elements (such as the explosive new technological genies)
which give a once-for-all shift upward to growth functions and expansion
paths (properly celebrated by Roemer and others). Sometimes these "endogenous"
elements are associated with particular historical, cultural, or social
customs (as is often the case with the "Asian miracle" literature),
and can lead to a form of path-determinism which can be daunting, especially
to more traditional growth modelers (with their one, two , or three factor
models from Harrod/Domar to Solow), or to those who focus primarily on
macroeconomic growth performance and smooth processes of change.
The analysis in this process is iterative. The economic model interacts with a social and political system of relations. (They
may be expressed as functional systems of relations, just as those in the
economic process. However each system of relations is interdependent with
the other. Hence the economic structure affects the social and political
structure and vice versa.) How does each economic process interrelate to
each relevant social process, group by group? A simplistic way of dealing
with this is to relegate the issue to another discipline (like sociology
or political science), just as the process of economic evolution is often
relegated by other social sciences "to economists" and treated
as exogenous. What we need to do for our subregions is to see how the economic
and social process intertwine, at least in the salient segments (leading
and lagging economic sectors, subregions, social groups) and how this interaction
is mediated by public policy and private in stitutions (state and civil
society). Some of our participants are actively building new institutions,
often transregional, to deal with the challenges of open regionalism.
New Regional Formations: The litmus of the international system
of exchange is the border region, or centers of export production, port
cities (in which imports are readily available), and international financial
centers. Not surprisingly, these are often far from capital cities or areas
in which the nation state and its respective regions achieve some degree
of reconciliation between their economic and social systems. That is why
decisions in Washington, Ottawa, or Mexico City may have m ajor repercussions
on Cascadia, the Southwest Corridor, Texas and Nuevo Leon, or New York.
And it is why Mexico City itself may have little concern for its border
regions, or for the affect of a major peso crisis on its increasingly exposed
subregions th at depend for their livelihood on international trade and
investment and the international market. Yet in order for such regions
to adjust to the new challenges, our research groups have already documented
ways in which they are restructuring their insti tutions on a transregional
and transnational basis. They must deal with shock-absorbers in order not
to be blind-sided by national (and international) policy changes or even
rumors (such as recent Congressional loose talk about "withdrawal
from NAFT A" or reneging on the $20 billion U.S. line of credit to
bail out the peso or the kind of political posturing that is so familiar
and irritating to Canadians who listen in to U.S. policy debates). Our
studies should address such considerations, incl uding the move toward
greater fiscal federalism which has the disconcerting effect of shifting
rising costs of the social safety net often to those regions least able
to address the challenge out of short-term gains from exchange, because
they begin at a disadvantage. These may impose a burden greater than their
ability to retain revenues. This is why we are attempting to encourage
the development of data series, or at least benchmark indicators, that
indicate how the revenue and expenditure base has changed, how much of
each is local, state, or federal responsibility and how this is likely
to change, and how that will affect the region’s global competitiveness.
New York and Mexico City are central here. In addition, regional coalitions
are subject to severe fiscal problems, since their interests are more common
than their revenue base, and there is little precedent for fiscal burden
sharing. This should be of particular importance to the cases in the Northwest
and Southwest.
An Iterative Process: Developing "Stylized Facts" for Each
Region: We have touched on a number of issues, most of which will begin
to be sketched out in the case studies. It is understood that with such
a broad framework, it is i mpossible with the time and resources provided
to prove specific relationships empirically. However we believe that more
than a heuristic framework (or "virtual regional characterization")
can be developed by the working groups for their respec tive cases. Each
will focus on those issues which are central to their particular case.
We will draw iteratively on the case studies, to modify the analytical
framework and policy recommendations. An introductory chapter of the volume
will introduce a generic political-economic model of a subregion facing
the challenge of open regionalism. Different typologies will emerge. Clearly
those of fairly "new" transborder regions, positioning themselves
to compete in the emerging Asia/Pacific and N orth American markets, have
a very different character and set of problems from those of older metropolitan
centers such as New York and Mexico City. It is our hope that the discussions
at Vancouver will help to shape the analytical framework of each cas e
study. There is no question that the dialogue will contribute importantly
to the formulation of a workable model that builds from micro to macro
behavior and decision-making, in an increasingly interregional and international
framework. We hope that t his synopsis, incomplete as it is, will begin
to respond to questions already raised by the case study teams, dealing
with conceptual issues, data gathering, information availability, and the
unique experiences of specific cases which by their individuali ty facilitate
the process of understanding comparison and contrast. Hopefully by looking
at individual North American experiences, in terms of a general an analytical
framework, we will be able to shed light on a global phenomenon that requires
much more attention to the grassroots, yet without losing the forest for
the trees. |