Mexico and the World
Vol. 2, No 3 (Summer 1997)
http://www.profmex.org/mexicoandtheworld/volume2/3summer97/china_nafta.html
China's Possible Response
to Mexico'’s NAFTA Challenge
ALAN ALEXANDROFF, WALID HEJAZI, and LEONARD
WAVERMAN
Centre for International Studies
University of Toronto, Ontario, Canada
INTRODUCTION
Although there remains considerable debate among
economists about the sources of economic growth, there is a great deal
that can be said about growth in China. In particular, few would disagree
that China's growth has been export led: over the 1980-1992 period, China's
trade has grown at rates of more than twice the world average. Liberalization
and decentralization of foreign trade and investment policies and the devaluation
of the currency have been important factors underlying this growth in Chinese
exports. Therefore, anything that may impede the growth of Chinese exports
and hence Chinese growth would be of interest to Chinese policy makers.
This paper was prepared with the possible impact in mind. However, the
policy recommendations set out below, suggest that it is possible for China
to respond to growing Mexican competitiveness within NAFTA. Mexican policy
makers and private sector actors should not underestimate the continuing
challenge China poses for Mexican trade and investment in North America.
It is perceived by many policy makers that Mexico's
trade structure with Canada and the United States is quite similar to that
of China's trade with these same countries. As a consequence of this perception,
it is believed that the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) that
includes Mexico will cause trade to be diverted away from China and toward
Mexico. Since the North American market, and the United States in particular,
is the largest market for Chinese and East-Asian exports, the creation
of a NAFTA that includes Mexico is of great concern to East-Asian policy
makers.
In assessing the impact of the NAFTA on China's
trade with Canada and the United States, some researchers have measured
the similarity (overlap) of Chinese and Mexican exports to Canada and the
United States (Magun and Sirimanne (1995)). However, such an approach is
incomplete because it implicitly assumes that trade and industrial structures
are exogenous. That is to say, this approach implicitly assumes that the
NAFTA will not impact on the trade and investment patterns of Mexico, that
Mexico will increase exports in its current export industries, thus displacing
Chinese exports in these same industries. Such a backward looking or static
analysis fails to incorporate the endogeneity of trade and industrial structures.
More importantly, it fails to take into account the expected impact that
NAFTA will have on Mexico's manufacturing sector.
In order to better measure the impact on China's
exports to North America, we must take the dynamic trade pattern effects
into account. The inclusion of Mexico into the NAFTA will impact on the
industries in which Mexico is internationally competitive, causing a change
in trade and industrial structures. Becoming part of a large and dynamic
market will affect the competitiveness of Mexican industries, including
some which are not currently export industries. These industries may as
a result of the NAFTA become competitive in supplying the North American
market, thus displacing other exports to North America. In order to undertake
such a forward looking dynamic analysis, we employ a "Porter-like"
framework.
The Competitive Advantage of Nations (Porter
(1990)) is an empirical study of 10 nations which isolates four national
characteristics which underlie a nation's ability to consistently improve,
innovate, and upgrade in particular fields. These are: factor conditions;
demand conditions; related and supporting industries; and firm strategy,
structure and rivalry. Porter also identifies a role for both the government
and chance. These factors form a system that together determine a nation's
ability to become internationally competitive in particular industries.
It is beyond the scope of this paper to discuss in detail China and Mexico's
relative positions in each of these categories. However, we discuss the
impact that the inclusion of Mexico into the NAFTA will have on Mexican
competitiveness.
Furthermore, we also discuss the necessary conditions
that must be satisfied by China if it is to continue to grow. This growth
has two dimensions: first, China must act to maintain its existing export
markets. The inclusion of Mexico in a NAFTA will likely affect Chinese
exports to Canada and the United States. Second, if export-led economic
growth is to provide high and rising standards of living for Chinese citizens,
Chinese growth must be in high value added production processes. China
must avoid becoming "trapped" in low-value added labour intensive
manufacturing. The policy implications for both of these dimensions are
clear and will be discussed thoroughly in this paper.
The purpose of this paper is three-fold. First,
we describe the pattern of Chinese exports to the world economy. Within
a Porter-like framework, we are able to make statements about the industries
that are emerging within China's competitive advantage. We draw a distinction
between the traditional notion of comparative advantage and the
more sophisticated notion of competitive advantage. Although comparative
advantage is an important determinant of international trade, it is the
notion of competitive advantage that is relevant in today's global markets.
Second, we compare and contrast Chinese and Mexican
exports to Canada and the United States. In particular, we assess the likely
impact the NAFTA will have on Chinese exports to North America. This involves
a two-step approach: a static analysis which is based on current trade
patterns, and a dynamic one based on the changes in the structure of trade
that will likely occur as a result of the implementation of the NAFTA.
To the extent that the NAFTA affects the competitiveness of Mexican industries
which do not currently overlap Chinese export industries, the dynamic analysis
will give quite different predictions than a static analysis. Furthermore,
policy statements based on a static analysis can be quite misleading.
The export similarity indexes of Magun and Sirimanne
(1995) show that the overlap in value of Mexican and Chinese exports to
Canada and the United States has been growing in the past 10 to 15 years,
and was 32 percent in 1991. This means that in a static analysis at least
32 percent of Chinese exports could be subject to direct trade diversion
effects. This analysis does not take into account the expected impact of
the NAFTA on Mexican competitiveness since NAFTA came into effect only
in 1993. For example, apparel forms a large part of Chinese exports to
North America, but only a small part of Mexican exports to Canada and the
United States. However, the provisions of NAFTA will relieve Mexico of
burdensome quotas in the North American market and impose ultra-strict
rules of origin upon the industry. These factors will result in Mexico
becoming much more competitive vis à vis China in supplying
apparel to the North American market. This is an example of trade diversion
that would not be picked up in a static analysis. Therefore, NAFTA's potential
impact on Chinese exports to North America may in fact be considerably
different than the static analysis would predict.
Third and finally, we draw policy implications
for the Chinese economy. These policy implications include liberalization
of both trade and investment environments. In order for China to maintain
access to existing export markets, progress must be made in terms of liberalizing
access to the Chinese market itself. This would improve China's negotiating
position with trading partners. For example, liberalization of Chinese
imports would very likely lead to reciprocal acts on the part of Canada
and the United States, as well as expedite China's admission into the World
Trade Organization. This would maintain China's competitive position vis
à vis Mexico in terms of supplying the North American Market.
Also, in order for a nation to achieve a high
and rising standard of living, it must achieve high and rising levels of
productivity in high-value added industries. Exports based on low wages
and low profits are not the exports that will lead to the highest and fastest
growing standards of living in the long run. China must establish policies
which will encourage a move into higher value-added industries. This would
require foreign investment, as embedded in these flows of foreign investment
is the transfer of technology that is needed to assist in the development
of a more sophisticated Chinese manufacturing sector.
Porter argues that in order to compete internationally
in high-value added industries, production must be based on advanced (created)
factors of production, not inherited factors such as low-skilled labour.
Given that a move from the initial factor driven stage of development to
the more advanced investment driven stage is typically financed by foreign
investment, it is quite important that the Chinese government improve the
investment environment in China. This includes measures that will provide
protection for intellectual property. The liberalization of the investment
environment is accentuated by the extension of National Treatment within
the NAFTA to member countries' foreign direct investment (FDI). This gives
Mexico an additional advantage given the complementarity between trade
and investment, and the important role played by foreign firms in the growth
of Chinese exports. China must improve its investment climate to encourage
FDI, and the NAFTA reinforces this need.
REGIONAL TRADE AGREEMENTS, TRADE DIVERSION,
AND TRADE CREATION
A free trade agreement is an economic integration
arrangement in which (many) barriers to trade among member countries are
removed. The NAFTA eliminates most trade restrictions between Canada, the
United States, and Mexico in manufacturing, extends National Treatment
to foreign investment and imposes a strict intellectual property regime.
Such a regional trade agreement is consistent with the principles of an
open multilateral trading system provided that trade barriers affecting
non-members are not increased. However, this is not to say that the creation
of such an arrangement will benefit-non-member countries. International
trade theory predicts that the creation of regional trade arrangements
give rise to both trade creation and trade diversion effects.
Trade creation occurs when members of an economic
integration group focus their efforts on the goods for which they have
a comparative advantage, and start trading extensively with each other.
Trade creation is good in the sense that it results in efficient low cost
producers in member countries' gaining market share from high-cost member
producers, as well as generating increased extra-regional exports. These
results occur because the efficient regional producers are able to offer
lower-priced and higher quality output than their competitors both inside
and outside the regional arrangement.
Trade diversion occurs when members of an economic
integration group decrease their trade with non-member countries in favour
of trade with each other. One common reason is that the removal of trade
barriers among member countries makes it less expensive to buy from companies
within the group, and the existence of trade barriers with non-member countries
makes it more difficult for them to compete. Therefore, trade diversion
can lead to the loss of production and exports from more efficient non-member
countries to less efficient member countries that are protected.
Non-NAFTA countries can therefore potentially
be made worse off as a result of the NAFTA. It is feared that trade diversion
in such an important market such as North America would slow export-led
growth prevalent in many East-Asian economies, including China. The extent
of Chinese trade that will be diverted will depend upon: the similarity
of Mexican and Chinese exports to the markets of the United States and
Canada now and in the future; the extent to which trade structures change
as a result of the NAFTA; and the existence of non-tariff barriers that
limit access for Chinese products or make them more expensive relative
to Mexican products. Furthermore, if trade and investment are complements,
then to the extent that the NAFTA brings about trade diversion, it will
also bring about investment diversion.
To make these points clear, consider the following
two extreme scenarios. First, assume that Mexico and China export completely
different goods to Canada and the United States. Furthermore, assume that
trade structures are exogenous. In this extreme case, NAFTA does not cause
Mexico and China to change industries in which they export (the industries
in which they are internationally competitive). NAFTA would in this case
cause Mexican exports to both Canada and the United States to increase,
but these exports would not displace Chinese exports to North America.
To the extent that the NAFTA improves growth rates within the NAFTA countries,
Chinese exports to North America would in fact increase. In this scenario,
therefore, China would be made better off as a result of a NAFTA.
Second, assume that China and Mexico export the
same goods to Canada and the United States. Then, the NAFTA could make
Mexican exports much more competitive relative to Chinese exports, and
a as a result Chinese exports could be displaced. Although the reduction
in tariffs will immediately make Mexican exports more attractive relative
to Chinese exports, Mexican industries may in the long run become more
efficient as a result of becoming a member of the NAFTA.
If we allow trade and industrial structures to
be endogenous, that is, we move to a dynamic analysis, then the inclusion
of Mexico into the NAFTA may cause the pattern of Mexican exports to Canada
and the United States to change. The impact of the creation of a NAFTA
on Chinese exports to Canada and the United States becomes ambiguous. This
ambiguity holds whether we assume that China and Mexico export the same
goods to Canada and the United States, or not. These scenarios are displayed
in Table 1.
Table 1. Likely Impact on Chinese Exports as
a Result of the Creation of a NAFTA |
|
Static Analysis:
trade structures
exogenous
|
Dynamic Analysis:
trade structures endogenous
|
China and Mexico export
the same goods to Canada
and the US |
China hurt
|
Ambiguous
|
China and Mexico export
different goods to Canada
and the US |
China better off
|
Ambiguous
|
Of course, the model that best characterizes
trade among these countries is somewhere in the middle. China and Mexico
do export some goods within the same industries to Canada and the United
States. We would therefore expect some trade diversion in a static analysis.
However, the picture becomes less clear once we move to a dynamic analysis.
We can expect that Mexican exports in current overlapping export industries
will increase, thus causing trade diversion. It is less clear what will
happen to current non-overlapping exports of these countries.
PORTER'S DIAMOND THEORY
The traditional factor proportions model predicts
that countries will have a comparative advantage in, and export those goods
which make the most intensive use of the productive factor they have in
abundance. Some argue (Porter, 1990) that this model, however, is insufficient
to explain the patterns of trade that we observe in today's global markets.
Raw materials, components, machinery and even many services are now available
to firms through international markets, thus making the success of a firm
depend less on factor endowments in the firm's home nation, and more dependent
upon the efficiency and effectiveness with which firms deploy the resources
available to them.
The traditional approach to explaining trade patterns
has also been supplemented by considerations given to macroeconomic conditions
and government policy. However, firms and nations have succeeded or failed
in spite of macroeconomic environments that vary widely. Furthermore, the
record shows that government industrial policies fail as often as they
succeed, even in countries like Japan and Korea.
Porter's approach attempts to explain the
following empirical observation: no nation is competitive in every industry;
nations succeed not in isolated industries, but rather in entire clusters
of interconnected industries; and the pattern of competitive clusters differs
markedly from country to country. Porter finds that nations and firms that
become internationally competitive in a given industry depend upon that
nation's or firm's ability to innovate and upgrade into sophisticated techniques
and processes. Therefore, in order to explain competitiveness, one needs
to understand the ability to innovate. In his study of 10 nations, Porter
identifies the following factors that are essential in the determination
of the ability to innovate.
Factor Conditions
Factor conditions refer to the availability and
supply of the basic inputs necessary to compete in an industry, such as
labour, arable land, natural resources, infrastructure and capital. These
necessary factors can be classified as either basic or advanced. Basic
factors are those factors which are inherited, such as natural resources,
and unskilled labour. Advanced factors are those that are developed through
sustained and sophisticated investment, such as human and physical capital.
Unlike the basic inherited factors, the advanced factors are created. Porter
argues that the advanced created factors are the most important to modern
industrial competition.
An abundance of basic inherited factors
may, in Porter's world, work to undermine rather than enhance a nation's
competitive advantage because their existence undermines the incentive
to upgrade to more sophisticated and improved products and processes. In
other words, the existence of an abundance of the basic inherited factors
may cause a country to become trapped in industries that utilize
these inherited factors. Since such industries are typically characterized
as low value added, utilizing unskilled labour, they have low potential
for converting the country into an industrialized economy that creates
wealth for its citizens.
Demand Conditions
Companies that gain competitive advantage internationally
in sophisticated industries often have a large market in their home country
in these same industries. Also, these companies have domestic customers
who are among the world's most sophisticated. These customers pressure
their domestic companies to meet high standards, encourage them to improve,
innovate and upgrade. In other words, sophisticated demand conditions provide
an advantage to local companies by forcing companies to respond to tough
challenges. If demand conditions are sufficiently sophisticated, and to
the extent that companies react to these demand conditions, then these
companies become competitive internationally.
Related and Supporting Industries
Related and supporting industries are industries
that are linked by common technologies, distribution channels, skills or
customers. Competitive, home-based suppliers of specialized inputs and
machinery create advantages in downstream industries in several ways. They
provide cost effective inputs in an efficient, early, rapid and often preferential
way. Proximity plays an important role in fostering close working relationships.
The exchange of know-how, and mutual pressures to progress, and the rapid
flow of information and technical inter-change increases the rate of innovation
and upgrading. Companies with home based suppliers also have the opportunity
to influence the supplier's technical efforts, shape specifications to
fit particular needs, serve as test sites for research and development,
and maintain senior management contact.
Firm Strategy, Structure, and Rivalry
In Porter's study, he finds that the dynamism
and pressure created by a vibrant local industry was perhaps the single
most important stimulus to innovation and upgrading in an industry—a result
that held independent of country size. Domestic rivalry provides
an essential motivation for firms to make the investments and take the
risks necessary to generate competitive advantage. Domestic rivalry is
more important than competition with foreign firms because proximity speeds
information and improves incentives to compete. Domestic competition negates
basic factor advantages and forces firms to develop higher order (more
sophisticated) and ultimately more sustainable advantages.
The Role of Government
The role of government is best understood by examining
how it influences the four factors above. The proper role of the government,
to Porter, is to improve the quality of inputs firms can draw upon, to
define a competitive environment, and to establish rules and regulations
that promote upgrading and innovation. The government can therefore play
an important role in shaping the pressures, incentives, and capabilities
of a nation's firms. Porter's government is not the role player that some
see in Japan, Korea and Singapore.
The Diamond as a System
These factors together form what Porter calls
a diamond. This diamond contains the determinants of competitiveness that
influence the capacity of a nation's industries to innovate and upgrade,
and hence to become competitive internationally. They constitute a dynamic
system that is more important than its parts. Over time, these determinants
are mutually reinforcing. The diamond is also an important determinant
of a nation's ability to attract mobile factors of production—the final
form of mutual reinforcement. Mobile factors tend to be drawn to the location
where they can achieve the greatest productivity because this is where
they achieve the highest return.
Stages of National Competitive Advantage
There are four stages of national competitive
development in Porter's analysis: factor driven, investment driven, innovation
driven, and wealth driven. All nations begin at the factor driven stage of competitive development. In this stage, internationally successful
industries draw their advantage almost solely from basic factors such as
natural resources or low cost labour (i.e., the inherited basic factors).
In the next investment driven stage of competitive development,
a nation and its firms actively invest in upgrading into modern and efficient
plants and methods, normally based on foreign technology. In the innovation
driven stage of competitive development, all four determinants in the
diamond are in place and work together to foster continuous innovation
and upgrading in a wide range of industries. It is in this stage that an
economy reaches it highest level of productivity. To Porter, the final, wealth driven stage is a stage of decline. It is in this stage where
the emphasis switches from wealth creation to wealth redistribution.
The primary distinction between the stages
of development depends on the nature of the competitive advantage and the
sophistication of the strategies, methods, and techniques employed. It
is here that we need to draw the distinction between competitive advantage
and comparative advantage. In a constant returns to scale production environment
that utilizes only inherited basic factors, it is clearly comparative advantage
that determines the patterns of international trade. In this environment,
the traditional factor-proportions theory of international trade would
predict trade patterns.
However, when production is characterized by increasing
returns to scale, utilizing developed advanced factors of production such
as skilled labour or sophisticated capital equipment, and in the presence
of barriers to trade such as transportation costs, tariff and non-tariff
barriers, language, culture and distance, then the concept of competitive
advantage is relevant. It is no longer simply the factor endowments that
determine trade, but how firms and nations utilize the factors available
to them in positioning themselves to get access to inputs necessary to
produce goods and services for export to foreign markets.
It is clearly the case that Canada and the
United States are in the innovation or wealth driven stages of development.
The diamond is complete, reinforced by mobile factors of production, and
there is a large amount of income re-distribution. Although there is tremendous
effort to maintain and enhance growth rates and wealth creation, this is
always done with consideration given to the impact on income distribution.
China and Mexico are in the factor/investment
driven stages of development. Both countries are developing industrial
sectors. In both countries, the source of competitive advantage is in large
part determined by the abundance of low-wage labour and it is in this sense
that these countries are in the factor-driven stage of development. However,
the development of an industrial sector indicates an investment driven
stage of development. Foreign investors are playing a large part in this
process as both countries have received large inflows of foreign investment.
Foreign investment in these countries is likely motivated by the abundance
low-wage labour and at the same time access to a particular market: the
North American market in the case of Mexico and the potentially enormous
domestic Chinese market in the case of China, as well as for exports.
However, there remain large reserves of
untapped labour in both countries. Consider Table 2 below. The labour force
participation rate in Mexico is much smaller than that of Canada, the United
States or China. However, Table 2 shows that 60 percent of the Chinese
labour force is in agriculture, whereas only 27 percent of Mexico's is.
We can therefore expect that Mexican labour force participation rates will
likely increase, increasing the supply of unskilled labour, and hence the
production of low-end manufactured goods in Mexico. To the extent increased
production is in the same industries as China, the more Chinese trade we
expect will be diverted. The exact amount is an empirical question.
Table 2. Labour Forces, Mexico, USA, Canada
|
Population 1992 (Billion)
|
Labour Force 1992 (Million)
|
Labour Force Participation
rate (%)
|
Proportion of Labour Force
in
Agriculture Manufacturing
|
China |
1,162
|
700
|
60
|
60%
|
17%
|
Mexico |
85
|
32
|
38
|
27%
|
15%
|
Canada |
27
|
14
|
52
|
4%
|
15%
|
USA |
255
|
124
|
49
|
3%
|
17%
|
Source: World Development Report,
1994.
As Mexico is integrated into NAFTA, Mexican exports
to Canada and the United States will increase. Therefore, Mexican production
capacity will increase. This will result in both increasingly efficient
production facilities, and an increased demand for labour. As labour force
participation rates increase, existing Mexican export industries may absorb
these workers, or these workers may enter new industries that overlap with
China's export industries. Although it is unclear what will happen, by
looking at the growth rates of Mexican exports, we can determine which
industries are expanding and which are contracting, and hence make an inference
at to what may happen to Mexican exports.
But it is certainly the case that Mexico's entry
into the NAFTA will give Mexico added momentum in completing its Diamond.
Given that Mexico will become part of such a large, sophisticated, and
advanced market group, it will have access to the factors necessary to
become internationally competitive. Of course, advantages in the entire
diamond are not necessary for competitive advantage in low skilled or inherently
resource-dependent industries. Therefore, the diamond theory would not
predict that China will be substantially displaced. It will always have
a competitive advantage in a number of industries.
Developing countries are often characterized
by the coexistence of some capital intensive industrial sectors with large
labour intensive, low value added manufacturing sectors. This industrial
structure is needed to employ the relatively large supplies of labour in
these developing countries. Given that there is such a large untapped pool
of unskilled labour in Mexico, it is likely that Mexico may begin exporting
in some current non-overlapping export industries, thus reinforcing the
trade diversion effect in our static analysis. This would imply an additional
source of trade diversion.
Since Canada and the United States are in
different stages of development than are Mexico and China, it is unlikely
they will have competitive advantages in the same industries. Canada and
the United States are internationally competitive in much more sophisticated,
higher value added industries. As barriers to trade fall, low-value added
industries in Canada and the United States that exist only because of protection
will disappear, being replaced by Mexican or non-NAFTA exports.
Although it is beyond the scope of this paper
to discuss in detail the industries in which China and Mexico are internationally
competitive, we can discuss the dynamic trade patterns of China and Mexico,
and make inferences on what this means for the future of China-North American
trade. We can also relate the inclusion of Mexico into the NAFTA to its
ability to compete internationally with China. This would require a study
of the impact the NAFTA will have on the competitiveness of Mexican industries.
For this, we turn to Rugman and Gestrin (1993).
FIRM, COUNTRY AND REGION SPECIFIC FACTORS
Rugman and Gestrin (1993) analyze the impact
that NAFTA will have on the competitiveness of North American industries.
Such an analysis is essential in estimating the impact that NAFTA will
have on Chinese exports to North America. The authors lay out a conceptual
framework in which firm specific advantages (FSAs) interact with country
specific advantages (CSAs) or region specific advantages (RSAs) to determine
which industries will become internationally competitive.
Panel (A) of Figure 1 shows the outcome
of the interaction of these advantages. A strong country specific advantage
or a strong firm specific advantage is defined as an advantage sufficient
to ensure competitiveness with respect to foreign rivals. International
competitiveness is assured when both country and firm specific advantages
exist simultaneously. In contrast, when both country and firm specific
advantages are lacking, then competing internationally with foreign rivals
becomes almost impossible. When one advantage exists and the other does
not, then the existing factor may or may not compensate for the non-existence
of the other. Nevertheless, the interaction of these advantages determines
the international competitiveness of industries. It is straightforward
to extend this analysis from country specific advantages to region specific
advantages. These two advantages are conceptually the same thing.
Figure 1:
The authors point out that investment liberalization
agreements such as the NAFTA can affect firm, country, and region specific
advantages. Panels (B) and (C) of Figure 1 summarize the impact the NAFTA
will likely have on the international competitiveness of industries within
North America, at the country specific level and the region specific level.
It is important to note that although several industries are strengthened
as a result of the NAFTA at the country specific level, no industries are
weakened at the region specific level. Industries which were protected
before the NAFTA lose their protection and face increased competition from
member countries' producers.
But member country industries remain protected
from competition from non-member countries' producers. This is the essence
of a regional trade agreement. It is to increase intra-regional efficiency
to the exclusion of non-members.
We want to consider the impact of the NAFTA
on the competitiveness of Mexican industries. At the country specific level,
we see there are no industries in which Mexico has strong firm specific
advantages. At the country specific level, therefore, all industries are
characterized as having weak firm specific advantages. Energy, telecom
services, and natural resources are industries within Mexico which have
been strengthened by the NAFTA (i.e., protection remains). Most Mexican
manufacturing industries are listed as having both weak country specific
advantages and weak firm specific advantage, and also, these industries
have been hurt by the NAFTA (i.e., protection removed).
The most striking feature of these results
is the characterization of the manufacturing sector as being hurt by the
NAFTA. Mexican manufacturing suffers from extremely weak firm specific
advantages. Under the terms of the NAFTA, most tariffs on manufacturing
will be phased out over the 10 year implementation phase (and most will
disappear in the first 5 years). While the adjustment to increased international
competition has focused on the sunset industries in Canada and the United
States, the Mexican economy is pursuing a wholesale restructuring of its
economy in anticipation of the NAFTA at a pace that has rarely been matched
in the history of economic reform.
The National Treatment provisions in the
NAFTA will result in large increase in FDI into Mexico from NAFTA members.
As Rugman and Gestrin point out, the Mexican manufacturing sector will
be transformed into a modern and efficient industry. It will move from
an industry whose competitive advantage was based solely on inherited basic
factors to one whose competitiveness is based on sophisticated advanced
factors of production.
Let us consider the Mexican automobile industry.
In 1994 alone, planned FDI projects amounted to $2.5 billion, $1 billion
from Chrysler, Ford, and General Motors, and $1.2 billion from Volkswagen
and Nissan. BMW and Honda planned $246 million in FDI. These transnationals
have introduced state of the art technologies and advanced organizational
practices in their Mexican affiliates. In other words, the Mexican automobile
industry has been transformed from a protected, fragmented and low productivity
industry into a fast growing internationally competitive industry. The
liberalization policies of the Mexican government resulted in transnational
corporations integrating their Mexican operations into their global production
networks. This is in line with Mexico's comparative advantage (United Nations,
1995).
The implications of this analysis for China
are obvious. Although both countries rely heavily on unskilled labour for
their source of comparative advantage, Mexico is fast becoming integrated
into international production networks. Therefore, among the class of low
value added industries which use unskilled labour, the transformation of
Mexico's manufacturing industry is moving Mexico out of the lowest value
added processes and into the more sophisticated processes, such as motorized
vehicles, industrial machinery, and petrochemicals. These are industries
which are not major exports of China. This will only serve to push China
further into the trap described by Porter. Also, provisions in the NAFTA,
such as those for apparel, will likely make Mexico more competitive in
these industries. Apparel is the major Chinese export to North America.
Apparel is also one of the fastest growing Mexican exports to Canada and
the United States. These results are reflected in the trade data to which
we now turn.
CHINA'S TRADE IN THE WORLD ECONOMY
Over the 1980-1992 period, Chinese exports
have grown at an average annual rate of 12.5 percent. This is more than
double the average annual growth rate for total world exports of only 5.4
percent (Figure 2). Over the period, Chinese exports have more than quadrupled,
whereas world exports have doubled. Mirroring the growth in Chinese exports
was similar growth in Chinese imports (Figure 3). Chinese exports and imports
were each roughly US $20 billion in 1980. In 1992, exports had grown to
approximately US $90 billion and imports to US $85 billion.
Composition of Chinese Exports
Table 3 gives the distribution of Chinese
exports by 29 commodity categories over the 1980-1992 period. In the 1980-1986
period, the top 5 Chinese exports accounted for over 70 percent of all
Chinese exports. This percentage has since fallen to 50 percent. In 1992,
the top 9 exports accounted for 70 percent of all Chinese exports. Therefore,
Chinese exports are becoming less concentrated. Over the 1980-1992 period,
four exports have consistently entered the list of the top five Chinese
exports, and three others entered the top five list over the period but
not every year. Consider the following summary table. Clearly, Chinese
exports are concentrated in low end, labour intensive light manufactures.
Table 4. Top Chinese Exports of the 13-year
Period 1980-1992 |
Industry |
Number of years in list
of top 5 Chinese exports
|
Percent of total exports
accounted for by industry
|
1980-92, average
|
1980
|
1986
|
1992
|
Agricultural Products |
13 of 13
|
|
|
|
|
Apparel |
13 of 13
|
|
|
|
|
Children Toys & Games |
13 of 13
|
|
|
|
|
Woven Fabrics |
13 of 13
|
|
|
|
|
Chemicals, Fats |
5 of 13
|
|
|
|
|
Office Machines |
6 of 13
|
|
|
|
|
Transportation equipment |
2 of 13
|
|
|
|
|
Although China does export some more sophisticated
manufactures, these form a small but increasing component of total Chinese
exports. We can see this by considering the industries that are the fastest
growing. Table 5 gives the export growth rates by industry. The ten fastest
growing exports over the 1980-1992 period were: office machines (42.2 percent),
television receivers (41.2 percent), telecommunications and sound recording
apparatus (37 percent), photographic apparatus and lenses (34.5 percent),
radio and broadcast receivers (32.9 percent), books and other printed matter
(32.1 percent), children's toys and games (31.2 percent), transportation
equipment (28 percent), electrical machinery (26.3 percent), and footwear
(25.3 percent).
Table 5. Growth Rates of Major Chinese Export
Sectors |
|
Growth Rates (percentages) |
Product |
1980-1992
|
1985-1992
|
1988-1992
|
Books and other printed matter |
|
|
|
Photographic apparatus and lenses |
|
|
|
Electrical machinery |
|
|
|
Telecommunications and sound recording
apparatus |
|
|
|
Office machines |
|
|
|
Footwear |
|
|
|
Professional scientific and controling
instruments |
|
|
|
Power generating machinery |
|
|
|
Non-metalic mineral manufactures |
|
|
|
Children's toys, games, etc. |
|
|
|
Apparel |
|
|
|
Rubber products |
|
|
|
Television receivers |
|
|
|
Wood and paper products |
|
|
|
Rubber and wood pulp products |
|
|
|
Fats and oils |
|
|
|
Watches and clocks |
|
|
|
Other products, not classified |
|
|
|
Radio broadcast receivers |
|
|
|
Metals |
|
|
|
Machinery |
|
|
|
Chemicals, fats |
|
|
|
Leather products |
|
|
|
Agricultural products |
|
|
|
Fabrics |
|
|
|
Coal, petroleum and gas products |
|
|
|
Fertilizers, metals, animals and
plant products |
|
|
|
Transport equipment |
|
|
|
Fabrics for clothing |
|
|
|
All Chinese exports |
|
|
|
The top ten fastest growing exports for the 1988-1992
period were books and printed matter (51.4 percent), photographic apparatus
and lenses (49.6 percent), electrical machinery (46.1 percent), telecommunications
and sound apparatus (45.3 percent), office machines (41.2 percent), footwear
(40.2 percent), professional scientific and controlling instruments (38.1
percent), power generating machinery (34.8 percent), non-metallic mineral
manufactures (27.2 percent), and children's toy (24.2 percent). Therefore,
seven out of the ten fastest growing industries over the entire period
were still growing rapidly over the-1988-1992 sub-period. The industries
that fell out of the top ten list were radio broadcast receivers, television
receivers, and transport equipment. The industries that replaced these
three industries in the top ten list were professional and scientific controlling
instruments, power generating machinery, and non-metallic mineral manufactures.
We can also make inferences about the impact these
growth rates will have on Chinese export structures. From Tables 3 and
5, we see that only office machines, children's toys and games, and apparel
are among the fastest growing industries and are also in the top five Chinese
exports. Machinery, chemicals (fats), agricultural products, and fabrics
are among the lowest in terms of growth rates. Therefore, it appears that
China is increasing its exports of low end manufactures such as children's
toys and apparel, and some higher end manufactures such as office machines,
but relatively decreasing exports in agricultural products, fats, fabrics,
and transport equipment.
In order to get a finer description of Chinese
exports, we consider Chinese exports at the 4 digit SITC level ranked by
the largest export shares (Tables 6 and 7). The top 50 exports ranked by
China's world export share comprised 21.9 percent of all Chinese exports
in 1980, and 41.8 percent in 1992. This list does not necessarily imply
that the industries for which China has the largest world export market
shares are also those industries which comprise the largest components
of China's exports by value. For example, in 1992, China controlled 81
percent of the world export market for caster oil seeds. However, these
exports totalled only $14 million, or 0.02 percent of all Chinese exports.
The top ten industries on this list only account for 4.8 percent of total
Chinese exports in 1984, and 1.6 percent in 1992. In other words, China
is the largest world exporter is some very small international export industries.
The fact that China dominates the caster oil seed market does not tell
us very much.
Table 8 gives a list of the top 50 Chinese exports
ranked by value. This list comprised 61 percent of total Chinese exports.
For the 1980-1992 period, the top 10 industries were footwear (4.8 percent),
outer garments of textile fabrics (4.2 percent), toys and games (3.7 percent),
petroleum and crude oils (3.3 percent), mens shirts (2.5 percent), undergarments
(2.2 percent), jerseys, pullovers and sweaters (1.9 percent), radio broadcast
receivers (1.7 percent), travel goods and hand bags (1.7 percent), and
cotton fabrics (1.6 percent). These top 10 industries comprise 27.6 percent
of total Chinese exports. The average growth rate by value for these top
10 industries was 21 percent, almost twice the average of 12.5 percent
for all Chinese exports.
The top 10 industries ranked by growth rates over
the 1980-1992 period were calculating machines (46.8 percent), television
receivers (41.2 percent), miscellaneous articles (37.8 percent), ships
and boats (37.2 percent), telecommunication apparatus parts (36.3 percent),
maize-corn (35.8 percent), appliances (35.4 percent), fabrics (35.4 percent),
radio broadcast receivers (32.9 percent), and children's toys (31.2 percent).
The average growth rate for these top ten exports was 37.0 percent, and
these industries comprised a total of 12.6 percent of all Chinese exports.
Of this list of the top 10 industries by growth rates, only 2 were in the
top 10 when ranked by value over the 1980-1992 period (children's toys
and radio broadcast receivers).
Table 6. Top 50
Chinese Exports in 1984 by World Export Share |
Product (4-digit SITC code classification) |
World Export
|
|
Share of All
|
Rank
|
|
Share
(%)
|
|
Chinese Exports (%)
|
|
Crude Animal Materials, N.E.S. |
94.54
|
|
0.06
|
1
|
Oil
Seeds and Oleaginous Fruit |
88.48
|
|
0.52
|
2
|
Raw
Silk (Not Thrown) |
74.56
|
|
0.68
|
3
|
Textile
Yarn, Fabrics, Made-up Art, Related Products |
68.97
|
|
0.08
|
4
|
Tea
and Mate |
67.65
|
|
0.08
|
5
|
Articles
of apparel and clothing accessories |
61.94
|
|
1.30
|
6
|
Castor
Oil Seeds |
60.29
|
|
0.11
|
7
|
Rice |
58.43
|
|
0.09
|
8
|
Essential
Oils & Perfume Mat; Toilet-Cleansing Mat |
57.50
|
|
0.11
|
9
|
Fixed
Vegetable Oils and fats |
54.93
|
|
0.08
|
10
|
Miscellaneous
Manufactured Articles, N.E.S. |
52.05
|
|
0.36
|
11
|
Crude
Animal and Vegetable Materials, N.E.S. |
50.80
|
|
0.12
|
12
|
Coal,
Coke and Briquettes |
48.21
|
|
0.39
|
13
|
Manufactures
of Metal, N E.S. |
47.88
|
|
0.40
|
14
|
Oil
Seeds and Oleaginous Fruit, Whole or Broken |
47.30
|
|
0.03
|
15
|
Coffee,
Tea, Cocoa, Spices, Manufactures Thereof |
46.85
|
|
0.35
|
16
|
Cereals
and Cereal Preparations |
45.53
|
|
0.65
|
17
|
Dyeing,
Tanning and Colouring Materials |
45.13
|
|
0.05
|
18
|
Meat
and Meat Preparation |
44.23
|
|
0.64
|
19
|
Crude
Fertilizers and Crude Materials (Excl. Coal) |
43.24
|
|
0.15
|
20
|
Silk
Worm Cocoons Suitable for Reeling & Silk Waste |
43.12
|
|
0.30
|
21
|
Tobacco
Manufactured |
39.68
|
|
0.02
|
22
|
Tobacco
and Tobacco Manufactures |
37.23
|
|
0.04
|
23
|
Sesame
(Sesamum) Seeds |
32.94
|
|
0.20
|
24
|
Vegetables
and Fruit |
30.55
|
|
0.33
|
25
|
Fine
Animal Hair, Not Carded or Combed |
29.79
|
|
1.11
|
26
|
Cotton
Seeds |
28.81
|
|
0.05
|
27
|
Metalliferous
Ores and Metal Scrap |
28.76
|
|
0.23
|
28
|
Palm
Nuts and Palm Kernels |
28.74
|
|
0.05
|
29
|
Textile
Fibres (Except Wool Tops) and their Wastes |
27.53
|
|
0.28
|
30
|
Basketwork,
Wickerwork etc. of Plaiting Materials |
25.70
|
|
1.27
|
31
|
Cotton
Fabrics, Woven, Unbleached, not Mercerized |
24.93
|
|
2.58
|
32
|
Swine,
Live |
24.46
|
|
0.95
|
33
|
Rubber
Manufactures, N.E.S. |
23.22
|
|
0.08
|
34
|
Horsehair
& Other Coarse Animal Hair (Excl. Wool) |
22.87
|
|
0.04
|
35
|
Under
Garments, Knitted or Crocheted |
20.77
|
|
0.03
|
36
|
Inorganic
Chemicals |
20.35
|
|
0.18
|
37
|
Paper,
Paperboard, Artic, of Paper, Paper-Pulp/Board |
18.38
|
|
0.06
|
38
|
Plants,
Seeds, Fruit Used in Perfumery, Pharmacy |
18.30
|
|
0.72
|
39
|
Hides
and Skins, N.E.S. Waste and Used Leather |
17.85
|
|
0.22
|
40
|
Tobacco,
Unmanufactured; Tobacco Refuse |
17.54
|
|
0.02
|
41
|
Bed
Linen, Table Linen, Toilet & Kitchen Linen, etc. |
16.08
|
|
1.50
|
42
|
Petroleum,
Petroleum Products and Related Material |
15.42
|
|
1.33
|
43
|
Hides
and Skins (Except Furskins) Raw |
15.40
|
|
0.01
|
44
|
Pottery |
15.37
|
|
0.02
|
45
|
Fabrics,
Woven, N.E.S. |
15.27
|
|
1.33
|
46
|
Vegetables,
Dried, Dehydrated or Evaporated |
15.05
|
|
0.33
|
47
|
Manufactured
Goods, N.E.S. |
14.71
|
|
0.55
|
48
|
Poultry,
Live (i.e. Fowls, Ducks, Geese, etc .) |
14.65
|
|
0.21
|
49
|
Art
of Apparel & Clothing Accessories, No Textile |
14.01
|
|
0.02
|
50
|
Total - All Commodities |
1.25
|
23881653
|
21.94
|
|
The top 10 industries ranked by growth rates over
the 1988-1992 period were-electro-thermic appliances (71.8 percent), electric
power machinery and parts (61.9 percent), refined sugars and other products
of beet and cane (58.8 percent), miscellaneous articles (54.8 percent),
insulated electrical wires, cable, bars, strip and the like (54.1 percent),
watches, watch movement and cases (51 percent), jewellery, goldsmiths and
other articles of precious metals (47.8 percent), small-wares and toilet
articles, feather dusters etc (45.7 percent), electrical appliances such
as switches, relays, fuses, plugs etc (45.2 percent), and coats and jackets
of textile fabrics (43.6 percent). The average growth rate for these industries
was 53.5 percent and these 10 industries comprise only 8.1 percent of total
Chinese exports.
Only two of the industries that grew the fastest
in the 1988-1992 period also grew quickly over the entire 1980-92 period:
miscellaneous articles and-electro-thermic appliances. But what is clear
from this list is the prevalence of light manufactures in the high growth
export industries. None of the fastest growing industries in the 1988-92
period were also in the top ten exports ranked by value in 1992.
In the early 1980s, manufactured goods comprised
the largest component of total Chinese exports. Petroleum products experienced
a large surge in growth in this period. Since 1985, the growth in Chinese
exports has been concentrated in manufactured goods and apparel. Referring
back to Table 8, we see that export growth has shifted from primary products
to labour intensive manufactured goods such as textiles, apparel, footwear,
sporting goods, and toys. These goods are in line with China's comparative
advantage, as reported in the World Bank's revealed comparative advantage
calculations (World Bank, 1994).
We next consider the link between the export industries
ranked by the highest value, ranked by highest world market shares, and
ranked by high growth rates. It is intuitive that the exports experiencing
the largest growth rates over the 13 year period 1980-1992 should also
be ranked in the top 50 industries by Chinese world export shares and value.
Of the top 50 industries ranked by export value, 21 also ranked in the
top 50 industries ranked by world export market share. Furthermore, of
the top 50 industries ranked by export value, 38 had average growth rates
that exceeded the average growth rate of 12.5 percent for all commodities
over the-1980-1992 period.
It is clear that the Chinese are specializing
in light manufacturing industries that are labour intensive and are relatively
quick to develop. This is the strategy used by the Tigers (South Korea,
Hong Kong and Taiwan) during the 1960s and 1970s. Now that these countries
have moved up the value added ladder, China is filling the gap in world
markets, just as the Tigers did earlier. China is doing in the 1990s what
the Tigers did in the 1960s and 1970s. These results are also consistent
with the revealed comparative advantage calculations of Magun and Sirimanne
(1995) which find that Chinese comparative advantage is shifting away from
primary goods toward low-skilled labour intensive manufacturing. The data
in the following table reinforce these conclusions.
Table 8. Top 50 Chinese Exports by Value, 1980-1992 |
Product |
Export Value
|
|
Growth Rates
|
|
|
($000)
|
Share
(%)
|
|
|
|
Rank
|
Footwear |
|
|
|
|
|
1
|
Other Outer Garments of Textile
Fabrics |
|
|
|
|
|
2
|
Children's Toys, Indoor Games, Etc. |
|
|
|
|
|
3
|
Petroleum, & Crude Oils |
|
|
|
|
|
4
|
Shirts, Men's, of Textile Fabrics |
|
|
|
|
|
5
|
Under Garments, Knitted or Crocheted
of Wool |
|
|
|
|
|
6
|
Jerseys, Pull-Overs, Twinsets, Cardigans,
Knitted |
|
|
|
|
|
7
|
Radio-Broadcast Receivers |
|
|
|
|
|
8
|
Travel Goods, Handbag, Brief-Cases,
Purses, Sheaths |
|
|
|
|
|
9
|
Cotton Fabrics, Woven, Bleach, Merceriz,
Dyed |
|
|
|
|
|
10
|
Trousers, Breeches etc. of Textile
Fabrics |
|
|
|
|
|
11
|
Maize (Corn), Unmilled |
|
|
|
|
|
12
|
Parts of apparatus, telecom &
sound recording equip. |
|
|
|
|
|
13
|
Bed Linen, Table Linen, Toilet &
Kitchen Linen etc. |
|
|
|
|
|
14
|
Overcoats and Other Coats, Men's |
|
|
|
|
|
15
|
Other Outer Garmens & Clothing,
Knitted |
|
|
|
|
|
16
|
Coats and Jackets of Textile Fabrics |
|
|
|
|
|
17
|
Watches, Watch Movements and Cases |
|
|
|
|
|
18
|
Art of Apparel & Clothing Accessories,
of Leather |
|
|
|
|
|
19
|
Crustaceans and Molluscs, Fresh,
Chilled, Frozen etc. |
|
|
|
|
|
20
|
Jewellery, Goldsmiths and Other
Art of Precious M. |
|
|
|
|
|
21
|
Misc. articles of Div. 58, resins,
plastics |
|
|
|
|
|
22
|
Fabrics, Woven of Continuous Synth,
Textil. Materials |
|
|
|
|
|
23
|
Yarn of Text Fibres, N.E.S., incl.
Yarn of Glass Fib. |
|
|
|
|
|
24
|
Furniture and Parts Thereof |
|
|
|
|
|
25
|
Anthracite, whether/not pulverized,
not Agglomerat |
|
|
|
|
|
26
|
Calculating Machines, Cash Registers,
Ticket & Sim. |
|
|
|
|
|
27
|
Television Receivers |
|
|
|
|
|
28
|
Cotton Fabrics, Woven, Unbleached,
Not Mercerized |
|
|
|
|
|
29
|
Fabrics, Woven, N.E.S. |
|
|
|
|
|
30
|
Small-Wares and Toilet Art., Feather
Dusters etc. |
|
|
|
|
|
31
|
Carpets, Carpeting and Rugs, Knotted |
|
|
|
|
|
32
|
Refined Sugars and Other Prod. of
Ref. Beet/Cane |
|
|
|
|
|
33
|
Cycles, Not Motorized |
|
|
|
|
|
34
|
Rotating Electric Plant and Parts |
|
|
|
|
|
35
|
Elect. App. such as Switches, Relays,
Fuses, Plugs etc. |
|
|
|
|
|
36
|
Elec.-Mech., Domestic Appliances
and Parts |
|
|
|
|
|
37
|
Knitted or Crocheted Fabrics |
|
|
|
|
|
38
|
Basketwork, Wickerwork etc. of Plaiting
Materials |
|
|
|
|
|
39
|
Ships, Boats and Floating Structures |
|
|
|
|
|
40
|
Pile & Chenille Fabrics, Woven
of Man-Made Fibres |
|
|
|
|
|
41
|
Manufactured Goods, N.E.S. |
|
|
|
|
|
42
|
Electro-Thermic Goods, N.E.S. |
|
|
|
|
|
43
|
Electro Power Machinery and Parts
Thereof |
|
|
|
|
|
44
|
Insulated, Elect Wire Cable, Bars,
Strip and the Like |
|
|
|
|
|
45
|
Motor Spirit and Other Light Oils |
|
|
|
|
|
46
|
Vegetables, Prepared or Preserved,
N.E.S. |
|
|
|
|
|
47
|
Manufactured Articles of Wood, N.E.S. |
|
|
|
|
|
48
|
Other Fresh or Chilled Vegetables |
|
|
|
|
|
49
|
Special Transactions & Commod.,
Not Class to Kind |
|
|
|
|
|
50
|
Total - All Commodities |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Table 9. China's Exports
|
1979 |
1991 |
Food
Raw Material
Manufacturing
Total |
20%
30%
50%
100% |
10%
12%
78%
100% |
Source: Magun, and Magun and Sirimanne
THE ROLE OF FOREIGN FIRMS
Foreign firms have played a key role in the growth
of Chinese exports over the 1985-1993 period (Table 10). Although in 1985,
foreign firms accounted for only 1.1 percent of total Chinese exports,
this number has steadily increased over the period, reaching 27.5 percent
in 1993. Furthermore, Lardy (1994) reports that foreign firms accounted
for 70 percent of total export growth in 1993. Lardy concludes that an
implication of this is that Chinese state-owned firms have not been heavily
involved in export growth, and hence total factor productivity in China
may not be increasing as fast as the trade statistics may seem to imply.
That is, the trade statistics are more a reflection of the activities of
foreign invested firms and less a reflection of the activities of state-owned
firms.
Table 10. Exports of Foreign Firms*
Year |
Exports (US$ millions) |
Percent of toal exports |
1985 |
320
|
1.1
|
1986 |
480
|
1.6
|
1987 |
1,200
|
3.0
|
1988 |
2,460
|
5.2
|
1989 |
4,920
|
8.3
|
1990 |
7,800
|
12.5
|
1991 |
12,100
|
16.8
|
1992 |
17,400
|
20.4
|
1993 |
25,240
|
27.5
|
*Exports are inclusive of those
produced by equity joint ventures, contractual joint ventures, and wholly
foreign-owned firms.
These results therefore clearly support the hypothesis
that trade and investment are complements, especially in the early development
stages. Furthermore, to the extent that trade and investment are complements,
and to the extent that exports are leading Chinese growth, then foreign
investment is an important source of growth. Recognizing the importance
of FDI has strong policy implications.
The Trade-Investment Nexus
The role of foreign direct investment (FDI) is
fast becoming recognized in the literature as an important determinant
of economic growth, especially in the Asia-Pacific region. International
trade theory has modelled multinational enterprises and international technology
transfer in some detail. However, data limitations prevent full implementation
of these theoretical results empirically. What studies do exist generally
find that FDI and growth are closely related. Some policy analysts therefore
treat trade and FDI as one in the same. Both Mexico and China have experienced
a tremendous increase in foreign direct investment over the 1980s and 1990s.
Consider Table 11.
Table 11. Inward Stocks of Foreign Direct Investment*
(US$ millions)
|
1985 |
1990 |
1993 |
1994 |
Mexico |
14,824 |
27,856 |
41,912 |
46,334 |
China |
3,444 |
14,135 |
57,172 |
90,972 |
Source: United Nations, 1995.
* In 1994, 35% of all inward stock
of FDI in Mexico came from the United States, whereas the US only accounted
for 2% of inward stock of FDI in China. These percentages are virtually
unchanged from their 1990 values.
However, these Chinese data are overstated as
they are approved FDI. Lardy (1996) reports that on a realized basis, Chinese
inward FDI is only $34 billion, less than that of Mexico. On a per capita
basis, therefore, Chinese inward FDI is tiny in comparison to that of Mexico.
Also, much of the investment in China is really Chinese money that has
been moved off-shore and recycled back into China disguised as foreign
investment. This is done to take advantage of incentives provided to foreign-invested
firms. Therefore, as Lardy (1996) states, China is not heavily dependent
on foreign capital to finance investment.
Many researches attribute the growth in FDI in
these countries to the shifting structure of comparative advantage in the
world economy. High wage countries lose competitiveness in labour intensive
products, and resource abundant countries tend to specialize in resource-intensive
activities. In trying to understand FDI patterns, economists refer to the
"flying geese" pattern of the stages of development, which is
akin to Porter's stages of development:
Stage 1. Production and export of labour
intensive manufacturing industries such as clothing and textiles, small
appliances and the development of some domestic oriented heavy industry
Stage 2. Production of basic manufacturing
goods and the establishment of export markets in goods such as steel, electrical
equipment, autos and chemicals
Stage 3. Shifting production out
of labour-intensive manufactures, and shift into component and other high
value added industries such as electronics, transportation equipment, materials
and services.
Although both Mexico and China are in the first
stage of development, the large inflow of FDI and the embedded technology
is allowing for the creation of sectors of the economy that are more advanced.
The creation of NAFTA and National Treatment will certainly assist Mexico
in this process. That is, although both countries are in the first stage
of economic development, and both are receiving large inflows of FDI, Mexico
is much further ahead in convincing foreign investors of the future. As
a result, Mexico has been very successful in creating, for example, an
automobile industry that is linked to the international production networks
of transnational corporations.
CHINA-NORTH AMERICA TRADE
China-Canada Trade. Chinese exports
to Canada and the United States are difficult to measure accurately because
of re-exports through Hong Kong. Hong Kong firms play an important role
in the marketing of Chinese goods to other countries. As a result, a majority
of Chinese exports to Hong Kong are re-exported to other nations. For example,
Chinese exports to Hong Kong totalled $32.9 billion in 1990. Of this $29
billion was re-exported to other nations. Once re-exports are accounted
for, the US was the largest market for Chinese exports (25 percent), followed
by the EC countries (19 percent) and Japan (12 percent). This is an export
structure similar to that of other East-Asian countries in the sense that
the US market absorbs a large portion of Asian exports, followed by Europe
and Japan. Hong Kong's share of China's exports in 1990 dropped from 54
percent to 6 percent once re-exports were accounted for (World Bank, 1994).
As seen in Table 12, 70 percent of all Chinese
exports to the United States are re-exported through Hong Kong, and 40
percent of all Chinese exports to Canada are re-exported through Hong Kong.
The issue of re-exports is therefore quite important in determining the
overall trade balance between any country and China. For example, without
taking account of such re-exports, Canadian trade data indicates that it
had a trade surplus with China since 1980 (Figure 4). However, once re-exports
are used to adjust both the Chinese and Canadian trade data, it becomes
evident that this surplus has in recent years turned into a deficit (Figure
5). Since detailed product data for re-exports are not available, analyses
of Chinese exports by detailed categories will be subject to this critical
bias.
Figure 5. Canada - China Trade, 1988 - 1992
Table 12. Share of Re-exported Goods in Total
Chinese Exports to US and Canada ($ Billions) |
United States |
|
1989
|
1990
|
1991
|
1992
|
1993
|
Direct Chinese exports |
|
3,529
|
4,755
|
5,592
|
7,342
|
7,016
|
HK re-exports of Chinese goods |
|
8,461
|
10,482
|
13,377
|
18,386
|
15,997
|
Total exports |
|
11,990
|
15,237
|
18,969
|
25,728
|
23,013
|
Share of re-exports |
|
70.57%
|
68.79%
|
70.52%
|
71.46%
|
69.51%
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Canada |
1988
|
1989
|
1990
|
1991
|
1992
|
1993
|
Direct Chinese exports |
0.78
|
1.0
|
1.2
|
1.62
|
2.03
|
2.39
|
HK re-exports of Chinese goods |
0.42
|
0.64
|
0.77
|
1.02
|
1.36
|
1.53
|
Total exports |
1.2
|
1.64
|
1.97
|
2.64
|
3.39
|
3.92
|
Share of re-exports |
35.00%
|
39.02%
|
39.09%
|
38.64%
|
40.12%
|
39.03%
|
Source: Lardy (1994), GATT |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Three products have
dominated Chinese exports to Canada over the 1980-1992 period (Table 13).
Apparel, fabrics, and agricultural food products have accounted for an
average of 70 percent of all exports to Canada. Apparel has accounted for
an average of 37.7 percent of total Chinese exports to Canada, followed
by fabrics with 22.3 percent, and agricultural food products with 10.6
percent. Although this may describe the current trading patterns, current
trends indicate a decline in the importance of these industries. These
exports have been growing at below average rates over the period. Although
the average proportion of total exports accounted for by these three exports
has been over 70 percent for the entire 1980-1992 period, the ratio has
not been stable over the sample. In the 1980-1987 period these exports
accounted for 75 percent of total exports, and this fell to 65 percent
in the 1988-1992 period. In other words, there is a shift underway in Chinese
exports to Canada, similar to that noted in the aggregate Chinese data
(see Figure 6).
Increasingly important Chinese exports to
Canada now include: toys and jewellery; iron, steel, and other metal manufactures;
footwear; electrical manufactures; chemicals; manufactured housing fixtures;
bicycles; meat, fish and dairy products; non-metallic manufactures; and
industrial machinery. Although these 10 industries only accounted for 14.8
percent of all Chinese exports in 1980, this ratio has increased to over
36 percent in 1992.
The products exhibiting fastest growth in recent
years have been more technologically intensive resource goods such as electrical
and metal manufactures, and given that China is presumably more dependent
on Hong Kong companies to market such products, the actual proportion of
these goods would probably be higher if re-exports were included.
China-US Trade
The United States is China's largest export market.
Chinese exports to the US, including re-exports from Hong Kong have grown
from $4.8 billion in 1986 to $25.7 billion in 1992. This translates into
an average annual growth of 28 percent (World Bank, 1994). Over the same
period, US exports to China (not including re-exports through Hong Kong)
have risen from $3.1 billion to $7.5 billion. Therefore, the US bilateral
trade deficit with China has climbed to $18.3 billion in 1992, second in
magnitude only to Japan. Lardy (1994) estimates that once re-exports from
Hong Kong are taken into account, the US-China deficit is closer to $12.5
billion.
The major Chinese exports to the United States
are displayed in Figure 7. In 1992, apparel accounted for 17.4 percent
of all Chinese exports, followed by toys, games and sporting goods (14.4
percent), footwear (13.2 percent), electronics (13.4 percent), leather
(6.0 percent), power generating machinery (4.1 percent), and plastics (3.1
percent). Chinese exports to the United States are therefore mainly in
labour intensive manufactures such as apparel, toys, footwear, and electronics.
MEXICO-NORTH AMERICA TRADE AND THE LIKELY IMPACT
THE NAFTA WILL HAVE ON CHINESE EXPORTS TO NORTH AMERICA
An examination of Mexican exports to the Canada
and the US (Tables 14 and 15) quickly dispels the perception that the export
structures of Mexico and China are very similar. Motorized vehicles and
parts together with mineral fuels made up close to 60 percent of Mexican
exports to Canada and 45 percent of Mexican exports to the United States
in 1992. These two products are of little importance for Chinese exports
to these two economies. Furthermore, the Mexican-NAFTA trade in auto vehicles
and parts, which has grown at an explosive pace in recent years, is mostly
of an intra-industry nature, and China is unlikely to be involved in this
area given the great distance between it and North America.
Magun and Sirimanne have calculated an export
similarity index for Chinese and Mexican exports to North America (Table
16).
Table 16
Export Similarity Index (ESI):
Chinese and Mexican exports to Canada & US
year ESI
1980 7.4
1981 6.4
1982 14.1
1983 13.0
1984 21.1
1985 29.7
1986 20.9
1987 22.1
1988 25.9
1989 28.3
1990 28.5
1991 31.7
Source: Magun and Sirimanne (1995)
This analysis indicates that almost one-third
of Chinese exports to Canada and the US overlap with Mexican exports (ie.
exports in the same product classifications). The most important industries
according to
their contribution to the overall export similarity index
in 1991 are: petroleum products; low-skilled, labour intensive products
such as men's outer garments; children's toys, games, and sporting goods;
footwear; light manufacturing goods like parts and accessories; furniture
and parts; electrical/mechanical domestic appliances; calculating machines/cash
registers; light fixtures and fittings, taps, cocks, and valves; and radio
broadcast receivers. Magun and Sirimanne therefore conclude that China's
concerns about the NAFTA are well founded and that Chinese industries will
lose some of their North American market share to Mexican firms.
Chinese exports to Mexico peaked at US$125 million
in 1981, and fell to US$25 million in 1985. They have since been rising,
reaching US$180 million in 1992 (see Figure 8). In the 1980-1988 period,
Mexico regularly enjoyed a trade surplus with China. However, this trend
reversed after 1988. Mexican exports to China have shrunk by more than
half since 1988, while Chinese exports to Mexico have increased dramatically
from under $10 million in 1986 to $180 million in 1992.
Synthetic fibres, metal manufactures, and chemicals
made up the majority of Mexican exports to China in 1992 (Table 17), while
the main Chinese exports to Mexico that year were light manufactured goods
such as bicycles, apparel, fabrics, footwear, and television sets (Table
18). Since Canada and the US are unlikely to compete with China in these
goods even with the lowering of tariff barriers brought about by NAFTA,
it is unlikely that the NAFTA will impact on China's exports to Mexico.
However, how will the NAFTA affect China's
exports to North America? To answer this question, we must determine what
will happen to Mexican exports to Canada and the United States, and hence
whether these Mexican exports will displace China's exports to North America.
For this, we turn to a dynamic analysis.
Dynamic Analysis
The major Mexican exports to Canada and
the United States are motorized vehicles, industrial machinery, mineral
fuels and agricultural food products. These are also among the fastest
growing of Mexican exports. These are exports that are not important Chinese
exports to Canada and the United States. Therefore, to the extent the NAFTA
increases Mexican exports in these same industries, there will be little
trade diversion.
However, a major Chinese export to North
America will likely be diverted: apparel. The provisions in the NAFTA will
rid Mexico of burdensome quotas in apparel and also impose strict rules
of origin on outsiders. Apparel is one of Mexico's fastest growing exports
to North America, and it is likely that we will see trade diversion in
this sector. Other sectors will also benefit from NAFTA provisions. And
it is here where the message from the Rugman model is important. Mexico's
entry into the NAFTA will give Mexico a large boost in its drive to complete
the diamond. As Rugman and Gestrin point out, the National Treatment provisions
within the NAFTA will cause a complete restructuring of Mexican manufacturing
industries. Clearly, Mexican firms will be more competitive than Chinese
firms in supplying North American markets. But given that much of Mexico's
manufacturing will be financed by FDI, using more sophisticated production
techniques, then it is also likely that Mexico will move to higher value
added industries. This will push China further into the trap of supplying
low-value added, labour intensive manufactures unless China attracts technology
intensive FDI.
Table 17.
Top Mexican Exports to China in 1992 |
Product (4-digit SITC category) |
Value |
Share of all
|
Growth rates of import
|
Rank
|
|
($000s) |
Mexican exports
(%)
|
1980-92
(%)
|
1988-92
(%)
|
|
Synthetic Fibres |
|
|
|
|
|
Iron/Steel Plates and Sheets |
|
|
|
|
|
Organo-Inorganic Compounds |
|
|
|
|
|
Condensation, Polyaddition Prod. |
|
|
|
|
|
Carboxic Acids |
|
|
|
|
|
Yarn Contain Synth. Fibres |
|
|
|
|
|
Parts of Int. Comb. Piston Engines |
|
|
|
|
|
Polymerization and Copolymerization
Products |
|
|
|
|
|
Mach. for Washing, Cleaning, Drying,
Bleaching Text |
|
|
|
|
|
Cotton |
|
|
|
|
|
Carpets, Cleaning and Rugs, Knotted |
|
|
|
|
|
Nitrogen-Function Compounds |
|
|
|
|
|
Elect. Filament Lamps and Discharge
Lamps |
|
|
|
|
|
Regenerated Cellulose; Cellulose
Nitrate, Etc. |
|
|
|
|
|
Synth. Rubb. Lat.; Rubb. Factice
Deriv. from Oils |
|
|
|
|
|
Automatic Data Processing Machines
& Units Thereof |
|
|
|
|
|
Calculating Machines, Cash Registers,
Ticket & Sim. |
|
|
|
|
|
Other Colouring Matter |
|
|
|
|
|
Semi-Manufactures of Tungsten, Molybdenum
etc. |
|
|
|
|
|
Fabrics, Woven of Continuous Synth.
Textil.Materials |
|
|
|
|
|
Miscellaneous Art. of Materials
of Div. 58 |
|
|
|
|
|
Crustaceans and Molluscs, Fresh
Chilled, Frozen etc. |
|
|
|
|
|
Quartz, Mica, Felspar, Fluorspar,
Cryolite & Chiolite |
|
|
|
|
|
Leather |
|
|
|
|
|
Antibiotics N.E.S not incl. in 541.7 |
|
|
|
|
|
Statuettes & Ornaments; Articles
of Adornment |
|
|
|
|
|
Albuminoidal Substances; glues |
|
|
|
|
|
Chemical Prooducts and Preparation
, N.E.S. |
|
|
|
|
|
Thermionic, Cold & Photo-Cathode
Valves, Tubes |
|
|
|
|
|
Insulated, Elect, Wire, Cable, Bars,
Strip and the Like |
|
|
|
|
|
All Other Products |
|
|
|
|
|
Total - All Commodities |
|
|
|
|
|
Table 18. Top Chinese Exports
to Mexico |
|
|
|
|
Product |
|
|
|
|
Bicycles |
|
|
|
|
Apparel |
|
|
|
|
Fabrics |
|
|
|
|
Footwear |
|
|
|
|
Television sets |
|
|
|
|
Children's toys |
|
|
|
|
Metal Manufactures |
|
|
|
|
Other products |
|
|
|
|
All products |
|
|
|
|
*Mexico did not import television
sets from China until 1988. |
While we cannot forecast which Mexican industries
will become world class, they are likely to be those best able to integrate
into North American production patterns. We would expect to see Mexican
industry upgrading and replacing East Asia imports especially as we have
noted in automobiles and components, apparel and electronics. Thus, we
feel that NAFTA will in the longer term, in a dynamic analysis, present
significant trade diversion for East Asia.
The only card the Chinese can offer here
is to offer an even more liberal investment climate. Although China's
investment climate is much better than its other East-Asian nations at
similar stages of development and even at a contemporaneous level, numerous
barriers still remain—local content requirements, trade balancing requirements,
restrictions in certain sectors and in access to the Chinese domestic market.
Only through the elimination of these investment barriers will China be
able to make itself more attractive for foreign investors than Mexico.
The lack of a legal institutional framework or commitments to intellectual
property and National Treatment are conditions that may be necessary to
encourage the foreign investment necessary. Without this deregulation,
China may, at least in the North American market, face superior competition
in many products in which it wishes to compete.
BARRIERS TO CHINA-NORTH AMERICAN TRADE
Although the Chinese government has decreased
its involvement in export planning, it remains heavily involved in the
import sector. Import patterns reflect a strategy of ensuring a supply
of raw materials and acquiring technology and have followed trends in planned
domestic activity (World Bank, 1994). To control China's imports, the government
uses various trade barriers such as tariffs, import restrictions, licensing
requirements, export subsidies, foreign exchange controls, and restricting
access to the service sector.
The weighted average tariff rate in China
is currently 32 percent, higher than the average of the developing countries
(23 percent) and clearly much bigger than the developed countries (5 percent).
In addition, imports are usually subjected to taxes, and customs valuation
has been inconsistent. The World Bank (1994) has estimated that approximately
50 percent of all Chinese imports are subject to some form of non-tariff
barrier, the most important of which are the designation of import rights
(32 percent of all imports). This practice involves the assignment of import
rights of certain products such as timber and fertilizers to one or a few
trading companies. The World Bank has concluded that import controls and
licensing are used to control three groups of imports: agricultural raw
materials subject to domestic control, critical domestic production goods
(e.g., steel and textiles), and nonessential consumer goods.
Aside from a few product areas such as textiles
and apparel, tariffs are not a significant trade barrier for Chinese exports
to Canada. Chinese textile and apparel products are also subject to Multifibre
Agreement (MFA) quota restrictions, although the Chinese quotas have been
allowed to grow at 5 percent a year as opposed to 1 percent or less for
Hong Kong, Taiwan, and Korea. The ultimate effect of these two restrictions
is to raise the price of Chinese textile exports by 40 percent to 75 percent.
Anti-dumping Laws
Canada's anti-dumping laws pose a serious
barrier to the continued expansion of Chinese exports to Canada. Under
the relevant provisions of Canada's Special Import Measures Act (SIMA),
China continues to be treated as a non-market economy in anti-dumping investigations.
Thus when Revenue Canada tries to calculate the export price or the production
cost of a Chinese product in question, it is allowed by the WTO to use
the export price or production cost of the product in a surrogate market
economy. This approach disregards any progress the Chinese have made in
price reform. Even assuming that it is legitimate to apply this surrogate
approach in anti-dumping cases against Chinese products at the present
time, Revenue Canada’s choice of using surrogate countries that have higher
levels of economic development than China is still questionable.
A review of Canadian anti-dumping cases
involving China undertaken between 1981 and 1994 reveals that most surrogate
countries in these cases do not appear to have been chosen on the basis
of cost comparability. In these eleven cases, six surrogates are developed
countries while the remaining five are developing countries at a higher
level of development than China. This surrogate approach led to high normal
values for Chinese products and resulted in large dumping margins. Also,
because the choice of the surrogate country is not known in advance, Chinese
producers and exporters, as well as Canadian importers are unable to predict
prices and implement stable pricing policies that comply with Canadian-anti-dumping
law.
Chinese goods are also heavily subjected
to non-tariff barriers in the US market. A World Bank study (1993) found
that 47 percent of all Chinese exports (and 62 percent of manufactured
exports) to the US were subject to quotas or other barriers in the US.
Furthermore, the effective protection from the non-tariff barriers range
from 40 percent to 80 percent, exceeding the protection rate of tariffs
(World Bank, 1993). An example of US barriers is the latest bilateral textile
agreement that took effect in 1994 which does not allow for an increase
in the import of Chinese garments in 1994 and only allows a 1 percent increase
in 1995 and 1996. As well, anti-dumping allegations against Chinese products
and its associated difficulties are a problem for the Chinese in the United
States.
CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The policy implications of this study are
clear. In order for China to maintain access to existing export markets,
and to compete successfully with Mexico, progress must be made in terms
of liberalizing access to the Chinese market itself. This would improve
China's negotiating position with trading partners. For example, liberalization
of Chinese imports would very likely lead to reciprocal acts on the part
of Canada and the United States, as well as expedite China's admission
into the World Trade Organization. This would improve China's competitive
position vis à vis Mexico in terms of supplying the North
American market.
The investment environment in China, and
the protection of intellectual property in particular are important issues
that must be addressed by the Chinese government. As Porter's study shows,
it is the advanced creative factors that are essential in the determination
of a country's ability to innovate, and to become internationally competitive.
The existence of an abundance of the basic inherited factors may cause
a country to become trapped in industries that utilize these inherited
factors. Since such industries are typically characterized as low value
added, utilizing unskilled labour, they have low potential for converting
the country into an industrialized economy that creates wealth for its
citizens. The abundance of inherited factors can therefore serve as a trap
that policy makers should be aware of.
Mexico's inclusion in the NAFTA and the
extension of national treatment are measures that will push Mexico
out of the low-value added trap. Mexico's exit from the lowest-value added
industries and its inclusion in the NAFTA will serve to further push (entrench)
China into the lower-value added industries, thus reinforcing the trap
Porter discusses. The provision within the NAFTA, for example with respect
to apparel, will assist Mexico's development in the sense that these sectors
will employ the vast pools of unskilled labour.
Liberalization of both trade and investment
environments are necessary conditions that must be satisfied by China if
it is to continue to grow. This growth has two dimensions: first, China
must act to maintain its existing export markets. The inclusion of Mexico
in a NAFTA will improve Mexican competitiveness as compared to China in
many higher value added industries, as well as some lower value added industries
such as apparel. If export-led economic growth is to provide high and rising
standards of living for Chinese citizens, Chinese growth must be in high
value added production processes, and to do this, China must both liberalize
its trade and investment environments. Otherwise, China will be "trapped"
in low-value added labour intensive manufacturing. Assuming that China
moves in the direction of liberalization, China can continue to pose serious
competition for Mexican prducers and exporters.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Canadian Department of Foreign Affairs and International
Trade (DFAIT), China - A Guide for Canadian Business; Ottawa, 1994.
Flatter, Frank and Richard G. Harris. "Trade
and Investment: Patterns and Policy Issues in the Asia-Pacific Rim,"
in Dobson, W and F. Flatters, editors, Pacific Trade and Investment:
Options for the 90s, 1995.
Lardy, Nicholas. "Economic Engine? Foreign
Trade and Investment in China," The Brookings Review, Winter,
1996.
Lardy, Nicholas. China in the World Economy.
Washington: Institute of International Economics, 1994.
Magun, S. and S. Sirimanne, "The Changing
Structure of China's Trade in the Global Economy," Centre For Trade
Policy an Law, 1995.
Porter, Michael. The Competitive Advantage
of Nations. New York: The Free Press, 1990.
Porter, Michael and The Monitor Group, Canada
at the Crossroads, Ottawa: Business Council on National Issues.
Rugman, A., and Michael Gestrin. "The Strategic
Response of Multinational Enterprises to the NAFTA," Columbia Journal
of World Business, 1993.
Statistics Canada. World Trade Database (CD-ROM).Ottawa, 1994.
Trefler, Daniel. "International factor price
differences: Leontief was right?" Journal of Political Economy 101: 961-87, 1993.
World Bank. China: Foreign Trade Reform,
Washington: World Bank, 1994.
World Bank. China Foreign Trade Reform: Meeting the Challenge of the 1990s, Washington: World Bank, 1993
World Bank. World Development Report, Washington:
World Bank, various issues.
United Nations. World Investment Report: Transnational
Corporations and Competitiveness. 1995.
Waverman, Leonard. "A Critical Analysis of
Porter's Framework on the Competitive Advantage of Nations," Research
in Global Strategic Management 5: 67-95, 1995.
ASA:asa (revs’d)
|